Constant elasticity of substitution
Constant elasticity of substitution (CES), in economics, is a property of some production functions and utility functions. Several economists have featured in the topic and have contributed in the final finding of the constant. They include Tom McKenzie, John Hicks and Joan Robinson. The vital economic element of the measure is that it provided the producer a clear picture of how to move between different modes or types of production.
Specifically, it arises in a particular type of aggregator function which combines two or more types of consumption goods, or two or more types of production inputs into an aggregate quantity. This aggregator function exhibits constant elasticity of substitution.
CES production function
Despite having several factors of production in substitutability, the most common are the forms of elasticity of substitution. On the contrary of restricting direct empirical evaluation, the constant Elasticity of Substitution are simple to use and hence are widely used.[1] McFadden states that;
The constant E.S assumption is a restriction on the form of production possibilities, and one can characterize the class of production functions which have this property. This has been done by Arrow-Chenery-Minhas-Solow for the two-factor production case.[1]
The CES production function is a neoclassical production function that displays constant elasticity of substitution. In other words, the production technology has a constant percentage change in factor (e.g. labour and capital) proportions due to a percentage change in marginal rate of technical substitution. The two factor (capital, labor) CES production function introduced by Solow,[2] and later made popular by Arrow, Chenery, Minhas, and Solow is:[3][4][5][6]
where
- = Quantity of output
- = Factor productivity
- = Share parameter
- , = Quantities of primary production factors (Capital and Labor)
- = = Substitution parameter
- = = Elasticity of substitution
- = degree of homogeneity of the production function. Where = 1 (Constant return to scale), < 1 (Decreasing return to scale), > 1 (Increasing return to scale).
As its name suggests, the CES production function exhibits constant elasticity of substitution between capital and labor. Leontief, linear and Cobb–Douglas functions are special cases of the CES production function. That is,
- If approaches 1, we have a linear or perfect substitutes function;
- If approaches zero in the limit, we get the Cobb–Douglas production function;
- If approaches negative infinity we get the Leontief or perfect complements production function.
The general form of the CES production function, with n inputs, is:[7]
where
- = Quantity of output
- = Factor productivity
- = Share parameter of input i,
- = Quantities of factors of production (i = 1,2...n)
- = Elasticity of substitution.
Extending the CES (Solow) functional form to accommodate multiple factors of production creates some problems. However, there is no completely general way to do this. Uzawa showed the only possible n-factor production functions (n>2) with constant partial elasticities of substitution require either that all elasticities between pairs of factors be identical, or if any differ, these all must equal each other and all remaining elasticities must be unity.[8] This is true for any production function. This means the use of the CES functional form for more than 2 factors will generally mean that there is not constant elasticity of substitution among all factors.
Nested CES functions are commonly found in partial equilibrium and general equilibrium models. Different nests (levels) allow for the introduction of the appropriate elasticity of substitution.
CES utility function
The same CES functional form arises as a utility function in consumer theory. For example, if there exist types of consumption goods , then aggregate consumption could be defined using the CES aggregator:
Here again, the coefficients are share parameters, and is the elasticity of substitution. Therefore, the consumption goods are perfect substitutes when approaches infinity and perfect complements when approaches zero. In the case where approaches one is again a limiting case where L'Hôpital's Rule applies. The CES aggregator is also sometimes called the Armington aggregator, which was discussed by Armington (1969).[9]
CES utility functions are a special case of homothetic preferences.
The following is an example of a CES utility function for two goods, and , with equal shares:[10]: 112
The expenditure function in this case is:
The indirect utility function is its inverse:
The demand functions are:
A CES utility function is one of the cases considered by Dixit and Stiglitz (1977) in their study of optimal product diversity in a context of monopolistic competition.[11]
Note the difference between CES utility and isoelastic utility: the CES utility function is an ordinal utility function that represents preferences on sure consumption commodity bundles, while the isoelastic utility function is a cardinal utility function that represents preferences on lotteries. A CES indirect (dual) utility function has been used to derive utility-consistent brand demand systems where category demands are determined endogenously by a multi-category, CES indirect (dual) utility function. It has also been shown that CES preferences are self-dual and that both primal and dual CES preferences yield systems of indifference curves that may exhibit any degree of convexity.[12]
References
- McFadden, Daniel (June 1963). "Constant Elasticity of Substitution Production Functions". The Review of Economic Studies. 30 (2): 73–83. doi:10.2307/2295804. ISSN 0034-6527. JSTOR 2295804.
- Solow, R.M (1956). "A contribution to the theory of economic growth". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 70 (1): 65–94. doi:10.2307/1884513. hdl:10338.dmlcz/143862. JSTOR 1884513.
- Arrow, K. J.; Chenery, H. B.; Minhas, B. S.; Solow, R. M. (1961). "Capital-labor substitution and economic efficiency". Review of Economics and Statistics. 43 (3): 225–250. doi:10.2307/1927286. JSTOR 1927286.
- Jorgensen, Dale W. (2000). Econometrics, vol. 1: Econometric Modelling of Producer Behavior. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. p. 2. ISBN 978-0-262-10082-3.
- Klump, R; McAdam, P; Willman, A. (2007). "Factor Substitution and Factor Augmenting Technical Progress in the US: A Normalized Supply-Side System Approach". Review of Economics and Statistics. 89 (1): 183–192. doi:10.1162/rest.89.1.183. hdl:10419/152801. S2CID 57570638.
- de La Grandville, Olivier (2016). Economic Growth: A Unified Approach. Cambridge University Press. doi:10.1017/9781316335703. ISBN 9781316335703.
- http://www.econ.ucsb.edu/~tedb/Courses/GraduateTheoryUCSB/elasticity%20of%20substitutionrevised.tex.pdf
- Uzawa, H (1962). "Production functions with constant elasticities of substitution". Review of Economic Studies. 29 (4): 291–299. doi:10.2307/2296305. JSTOR 2296305.
- Armington, P. S. (1969). "A theory of demand for products distinguished by place of production". IMF Staff Papers. 16 (1): 159–178. doi:10.2307/3866403. JSTOR 3866403.
- Varian, Hal (1992). Microeconomic Analysis (Third ed.). New York: Norton. ISBN 0-393-95735-7.
- Dixit, Avinash; Stiglitz, Joseph (1977). "Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diversity". American Economic Review. 67 (3): 297–308. JSTOR 1831401.
- Baltas, George (2001). "Utility-Consistent Brand Demand Systems with Endogenous Category Consumption: Principles and Marketing Applications". Decision Sciences. 32 (3): 399–421. doi:10.1111/j.1540-5915.2001.tb00965.x.