Credibility thesis
The credibility thesis is a proposed heterodox theoretical framework for understanding how societal institutions or social rules come about and evolve. It posits that institutions emerge from intentional institution-building but never in the originally intended form.[1] Instead, institutional development is endogenous and spontaneously ordered and institutional persistence can be explained by their credibility,[2] which is provided by the function that particular institutions serve rather than their theoretical or ideological form. The credibility thesis can be applied to explain, for example, why purported institutional improvements do not take hold as part of structural adjustment programs, while other economies in the developing world deliver growth despite absence of clear and strong market mechanisms such as indisputable private property rights or clearly delineated and registered land tenure. The thesis has been applied to explain the failure and success of institutional reforms for various sectors and property rights, including but not limited to, land, housing, informal housing and slums, natural resources, climate change policy and environmental policy.
Part of a series on |
Economics |
---|
Postulates of the credibility thesis
According to the credibility thesis, institutional persistence, meaning the survival and change of particular institutions through time is determined by the function of the institution and actors' expectations of the institution to play that function. The Credibility Thesis has put forward “that what ultimately determines the performance of institutions is not their form in terms of formality, privatization, or security, but their spatially and temporally defined function. In different wording, institutional function presides over form; the former can be expressed by its credibility, that is, the perceived social support at a given time and space.”[1] Or, as Pero and Smith phrased “institutional credibility refers to peoples’ acceptance of an institution based on their perceptions of that institutions’ accountability, representation, legitimacy, transparency, fairness and justice.”[3]
In light of the above, the thesis predicts that institutions that persist over time likely are credible, thus functional. If not, they would have changed or gone extinct. This principle holds for whatever form an institution may assume, regardless whether it is formal or informal, public or private, secure or insecure. A typical example is sharecropping, which has been regarded as economically inefficient[4] or "second-best".[5] However, its persistence throughout the ages has challenged this premise,[6] leading others to conclude that it is efficient, thus credible and functional.[7] That credibility has been confirmed in other studies.[8][9][10] In this context, Fan et al. noted: “Compared with other institutional theories, the credibility thesis places more emphasis on the function of the institution. (…) The credibility thesis explains successfully why some seemingly imperfect institutions, even without clear property rights, have persisted and been championed, while other seemingly perfect institutions have had poor operation effects.”[11]
Changes in institutional arrangements, such as changes from informal land tenure and informal housing to a formalized real estate market or gradually declining prevalence of formal marriage or customary rights, are brought about by rule-making in a multi-actor playing field, where even the strongest actors cannot fully dictate institutional arrangements. In effect, when powerful actors exogenously impose institutions that contradict the evolutionary flow of endogenously emerged functions, the newly designed arrangements will invariably develop into "empty institutions" and "non credible" institutions.[12]
An institution that appears stable and unchanging over time is often alleged to exist in an equilibrium wherein actors' conflicting interests on what form the institution should take are locked in a frozen conflict. For example, whether land holdings should be registered in a cadastre or if informal exchange of payment for use rights can suffice as confirmation of a land sale, constitute two possible institutional arrangements and either can be beneficial to different actors' interests. That no actor perceives an immediate opportunity to change the arrangement to their advantage is a sign of the credibility of the assignment and the source of the equilibrium of institutional arrangement. However, in actuality disequilibrium characterises institutional arrangements and equilibrium is transitory and rare. What is perceived as persistence of institutions is, in fact, the occurrence of infinitesimally small institutional changes over time under a veneer of apparent stability. In this context, the credibility thesis is predicated upon the notion of dynamic disequilibrium.[13] It is also why in this respect the credibility theory is juxtaposed to structural functionalism, which is based on presupposed equilibrium.[14][15]
A series of underlying postulates for the credibility thesis has been proposed:
- Institutions are the resultant of unintentional development. Although actors have intentions, there is no agency that can externally or exogenously design institutions, as actors' actions are part of the same endogenous game. Institutions emerge as an unanticipated outcome of actors' multitudinous interactions, in effect, are the result of an autonomous, Unintended Intentionality.[16]
- Institutional change is driven by disequilibrium. Contrary to the notion that institutions settle around equilibrium, actors' interactions are seen as an ever-changing and conflicting process in which stable status is never reached. One could see it as a "Dynamic Disequilibrium" or institutional change as perpetual alteration, yet, with alternating speeds of change; sometimes, imperceptibly slow, sometimes, sudden and with shocks.[16]
- Institutional Form is subordinate to Function. In other words, functional adaptation as evident through the use and disuse of institutions over time and space is what matters for understanding their role in development, not their appearance.[1]
Key concepts
Term | Definition | Example |
---|---|---|
Credibility | Perceived social support of an institutional arrangement at a given time and space; a measure of individual actors' aggregate perceptions of an institution as a jointly shared arrangement[17] | Informal settlements[18] and extra-legal housing that provide non-state social welfare for low-income residents.[19] |
Institutional function | The use that a particular institutional arrangement can provide to actors.[20] | In the agricultural economy, land is a primary asset from a subsistence point of view: it provides food security, enables utilization of family labour, and reduces vulnerability[21][22] The agricultural lease system in China functions as a social welfare net for the vast surplus of China's rural labour.[1][23] |
Empty institution | “[Institutional] compromises over sensitive political issues. The interests opposed to them ensure that they are established in such a way that they cannot achieve their aims, whereas the interests supporting them win a pyrrhic victory as their rules, as represented by the new institution, have no practical impact on social actors’ behaviour".[24] | Vilhelm Aubert observed that the Housemaid Law in Norway regulating the working conditions of domestic workers in Norway was on the books and technically being implemented but had not any effect.[25] |
Non-credible institution | An institution that is being enforced by a powerful actor, complied by but not accepted by others. | Expropriation of customary Native Title for dam-building and privatization of common property of indigenous peoples in Malaysia.[26] Evictions of peasants and urban citizens in China.[27] |
Dynamic disequilibrium | Contrary to the concept that institutions settle around equilibrium, actors’ interactions are defined as an ever-changing and conflicting process in which a stable status is never achieved. It will be proposed … as a Theorem on “Dynamic Disequilibrium”: institutional change as a process of perpetual alteration, however, by which the pace of change varies; at times imperceptibly slow, and at other times, sudden and with shocks.[16] | "[O]ngoing subtle shifts beneath the surface of apparently stable formal institutions."[28] |
Institutional form | The categorical description of institutional arrangements. | Secure, private, formal as opposed to fuzzy, common, and customary property rights.[29] |
Methodological approaches
Nail house | |
---|---|
"Given that all involved actors are constantly interested in changing institutional design, credibility cannot be measured by directly asking respondents whether they find an institution credible.
Instead it has to be operationalized through proxies, such as the level of conflict that an institution generates, the extent of 'institutional robustness' expressed as a function of institutional lifespan and flexibility, the degree to which an institution facilitates or frustrates overall socio-economic, political and cultural change, and the extent to which an institution fulfils the functions it ought to perform in the eyes of social actors."[31]
Such opening of the black box of institutions is possible using mixed methods to describe institutions in detail over time and space, which serves as an archaeology of institutions. The archaeology of institutions can be understood as "an approach by which the change of institutions is meticulously recorded, interpreted and studied through the collection of data from every possible source, regardless of whether that is socio-economic, historical, ethno-anthropological, geographical, psychological or legal-political."[17] An example of this, is the history of China's titling[32] and housing ownership.[33]
While predominantly applied to land-related institutions, this approach could be applied to analysis of other means of production, such as capital (e.g. banks and industries),[34] labor (trade unions)[35] or beyond[36][37] (water management and notaries).
The proxies that can be used to measure credibility include the following:
- Actors' aggregate perceptions of institutions, which can be operationalized according to the FAT Institutional Framework (in other words, an assessment of Formal, Actual and Targeted institutions);[26]
- Actors' aggregate perceptions of conflict generated by institutions in terms of "incidence, frequency, intensity (e.g., measured in terms of economic costs), the length (in time), and the nature (e.g., violent/non-violent)";[1]
- Speed of institutional change through an institutional archaeology of temporal changes in the formal property rights structure.[16]
When credibility is assessed through these proxies, a better sense can be obtained of the current function that institutions fulfil for a group of actors. In result, one is likely better positioned to predict institutional interventions that might rally social support. Depending on the level of credibility, these can be envisioned as positioned on a gradient from condoning or non-intervention to co-opting, facilitating, prohibiting and ordaining.
The CSI Checklist (Credibility Scales and Intervention)[17] was developed for this purpose.
Credibility level / trend | Institutional intervention | Desired effect |
---|---|---|
High | Condoning | Accepting praxis by non-intervention |
Medium high | Co-opting | Formalizing what is done |
Neutral | Facilitating | Supporting what needs to be done |
Medium low | Prohibiting | Dictating what shall not be done |
Low | Ordaining | Commanding what must be done |
Apart from studying credibility in real-life situations, the particular premises of the theory – endogeneity, dis-equilibrium, and functional adaptation – make it also suitable for simulation in agent-based models.
Emergence and reception of the theory
The question of credibility first emerged along with concern about certain institutional interventions failing. In the mid-20th century Vilhelm Aubert noted that the Housemaid Law in Norway had been implemented but flaunted by all involved actors.[25] The concept of credibility was initially coined as an explanandum for the success and failure of Western monetary, anti-inflationary policies in the 1970s.[1] A concern for the credibility of policy emerged in the latter half of the 20th century in response to frequently observed failures of neoliberal structural adjustments in the developing world associated with the Washington Consensus. Institutional reform, such as privatization, failed to deliver the predicted economic growth, not because of lacking credible commitment on part of actors but due to the absence of endogenous credibility.[2][38] For this reason, Grabel noted that “credibility is always secured endogenously (. . .) rather than exogenously by virtue of the epistemological status of the theory that promotes it.”[2]
In contrast, the growth of the Chinese economy despite lack of many institutions considered to be essential for economic growth indicated that institutional arrangements do not necessarily determine economic outcomes, and also at the same time economic development does not automatically lead to teleologically predetermined institutional forms.[39][40] This has been particularly striking in the case of real estate sector in China.[41][42] In this context, there is a growing body of research suggesting one should focus on the circular cumulative causation aspects of function or quality of institutional performance rather than their form.[43][44][45] As noted by Ha-Joon Chang: “a big problem that dogs the current orthodox literature on development is its inability to clearly distinguish between the forms and functions of institutions.”[46]
The term credibility thesis was put forth by Peter Ho in 2014.[1] In a review of the credibility thesis, Delilah Griswold contended that "credibility is a powerful metric by which to understand and evaluate tenure systems. Importantly, understanding the credibility of a given institution requires analysis outside of theory and politics, analysis that is locally and temporally specific and multilayered."[47] Benjamin Davy described it as a “rallying call of function presides over form” which “takes a fresh approach to credibility, land policy, and property theory. Initially developed with regard to land policy in main-land China, the credibility of property rights is also interesting from the perspective of Western property theory.”[48] George Lin deemed the thesis “inspirational, innovative, and provocative with great potentials to advance theoretical inquiry into the intriguing nature of China's developmental model in a rapidly changing world.”[16] The theoretical and methodological groundwork on the credibility thesis was awarded with the William Kapp Prize by the European Association for Evolutionary Political Economy.[49]
Application
The credibility thesis was developed to explain the apparent contradiction between China’s insecure land tenure and the support it rallied by farmers. Since the Household Contract Responsibility System replaced collective farming of the People’s Communes in the mid-1980s, farm households are allowed to lease agricultural land up to 30 years. Although the security of the lease is protected by law, the contracted land has been subjected to frequent reallocations by the village collective in response to demographic changes. Markedly, studies have found a high support for the land reallocations – and thus, an insecure tenure – by the majority of the farmers. This finding has been confirmed in consecutive research over three decades since the early 1990s.[50][51][52][53]
In the years after it was mooted, the credibility thesis has been applied to various sectors and resources, including land, [42] [54] slums and informal settlements, [18] affordable and commercial housing, [19] grasslands, [11] [38] forests, [55] mineral resources, [56] water management, [57][37] apartment and strata rights, [58] customary land rights, [59][26] climate and environmental policy, [60] and issues of urbanization and planning.[61] In addition, the thesis has also been used to explain property rights changes of labor markets,[35] intellectual property rights and technology, and financial institutions.[34]
The contributions of these studies to the understanding of institutions relate to:
1) Falsifying the relation between form and performance. Research has demonstrated that private, formal, and secure institutions may fail to deliver on their predicted positive performance.[37][26][35] Contrarily, other research has ascertained that public, informal, and insecure property rights are not economically inefficient, but functional and credible.[42][18][34]
2) Advancing the methodology and measurement of credibility, such as through refinement of the FAT Institutional Framework in relation to socio-ecological systems;[62] development of the Conflict Analysis Model;[63] and calculation of endogenous transaction costs as a measure of credibility;[11]
3) Assessing the functions of institutions, such as for political influence,[18] social welfare,[64] sustainability,[38] the catering for traditional markets,[56] and social cohesion.[19]
4) Examining conditions for diminishing credibility[12][65][27] due to the imposition of institutional arrangements on hitherto credible property rights.
See also
- Emergence
- Endogeneity
- Spontaneous order
- Lamarckism (the use and disuse of function determines the persistence, change or disappearance of institutions)
- Circular cumulative causation
- Form follows function (Architecture)
Related theories and theoretical bodies
References
- Ho, Peter (September 2014). "The "credibility thesis" and its application to property rights: (In)Secure land tenure, conflict and social welfare in China". Land Use Policy. 40: 13–27. doi:10.1016/j.landusepol.2013.09.019.
- Grabel, Ilene (2000). "The political economy of 'policy credibility': the new-classical macroeconomics and the remaking of emerging economies". Cambridge Journal of Economics. 24 (1): 1–19. doi:10.1093/cje/24.1.1.
- Pero, Lionel V.; Smith, Timothy F. (2008-01-16). "Institutional credibility and leadership: critical challenges for community-based natural resource governance in rural and remote Australia". Regional Environmental Change. Springer Science and Business Media LLC. 8 (1): 15–29. doi:10.1007/s10113-007-0042-4. ISSN 1436-3798. S2CID 154099360.
- Issawi, Charles (1957). "Farm Output under Fixed Rents and Share Tenancy". Land Economics. 33 (1): 74–77. doi:10.2307/3144295. JSTOR 3144295.
- Stiglitz, Joseph E. (1974). "Incentives and Risk Sharing in Sharecropping" (PDF). The Review of Economic Studies. 41 (2): 219–255. doi:10.2307/2296714. JSTOR 2296714.
- Byres, T. J. (1983). "Historical perspectives on sharecropping". The Journal of Peasant Studies. 10 (2–3): 7–40. doi:10.1080/03066158308438195.
- "Private Property Rights and Sharecropping". Journal of Political Economy. 76 (6): 1107–1122. 1968. doi:10.1086/259477. S2CID 153568071.
- Kassie, Menale; Holden, Stein (2007). "Sharecropping efficiency in Ethiopia: threats of eviction and kinship". Agricultural Economics. 37 (2–3): 179–188. doi:10.1111/j.1574-0862.2007.00264.x.
- Bhandari, Ravi (2007-09-11). "The role of social distance in sharecropping efficiency". Journal of Economic Studies. 34 (4): 290–310. doi:10.1108/01443580710817425. Retrieved 2017-01-14.
- José‐María Caballero (1983). "Sharecropping as an efficient system: Further answers to an old puzzle". The Journal of Peasant Studies. 10 (2–3): 107–118. doi:10.1080/03066158308438200.
- Fan, Shengyue; Yang, Jinfei; Liu, Wenwen; Wang, He (2019). "Institutional Credibility Measurement Based on Structure of Transaction Costs: A Case Study of Ongniud Banner in the Inner Mongolia Autonomous Region". Ecological Economics. Elsevier BV. 159: 212–225. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2019.01.019. ISSN 0921-8009. S2CID 159132509.
- Ho, Peter (2016). "Empty institutions, non-credibility and pastoralism: China's grazing ban, mining and ethnicity". The Journal of Peasant Studies. 43 (6): 1145–1176. doi:10.1080/03066150.2016.1239617. S2CID 157632052.
- Ho, Peter (2018). "A theorem on dynamic disequilibrium: Debunking path dependence and equilibrium via China's urban property (1949–1998)" (PDF). Land Use Policy. Elsevier BV. 79: 863–875. doi:10.1016/j.landusepol.2016.10.023. ISSN 0264-8377.
- Parsons, Talcott (1985). Talcott Parsons on institutions and social evolution : selected writings. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. ISBN 978-0-226-64749-4.
- Parsons, Talcott (1964). The Social system. New York London: Free Press Collier Macmillan. ISBN 978-0-02-924190-5.
- Ho, Peter (2017-10-13). Unmaking China's Development. Cambridge University Press. doi:10.1017/9781316145616. ISBN 978-1-316-14561-6. S2CID 158677325.
- Ho, Peter (2016). "An endogenous theory of property rights: opening the black box of institutions". The Journal of Peasant Studies. 43 (6): 1121–1144. doi:10.1080/03066150.2016.1253560.
- Zhang, Yue (2018). "The credibility of slums: Informal housing and urban governance in India". Land Use Policy. Elsevier BV. 79: 876–890. doi:10.1016/j.landusepol.2017.05.029. ISSN 0264-8377.
- Celhay, Pablo A.; Gil, Diego (2020). "The function and credibility of urban slums: Evidence on informal settlements and affordable housing in Chile". Cities. Elsevier BV. 99: 102605. doi:10.1016/j.cities.2020.102605. ISSN 0264-2751. S2CID 214046163.
- Ho, Peter (2018). "Institutional function versus form: The evolutionary credibility of land, housing and natural resources" (PDF). Land Use Policy. Elsevier BV. 75: 642–650. doi:10.1016/j.landusepol.2018.02.001. ISSN 0264-8377.
- Guhan, S (1994). "Social Security Options for Developing Countries". International Labour Review. 133 (35). Retrieved 18 June 2015.
- Davy, Benjamin; Davy, Ulrike; Leisering, Lutz (2013-05-27). "The global, the social and rights. New perspectives on social citizenship". International Journal of Social Welfare. Wiley. 22: S1–S14. doi:10.1111/ijsw.12041. ISSN 1369-6866.
- Cai, Meina (2016). "Land for welfare in China". Land Use Policy. Elsevier BV. 55: 1–12. doi:10.1016/j.landusepol.2016.03.014. ISSN 0264-8377.
- Peter (2005). Institutions in transition: land ownership, property rights, and social conflict in China. Oxford New York: Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0-19-928069-8.
- Aubert, Vilhelm (2013). "Some Social Functions of Legislation". Acta Sociologica. 10 (1/2): 1087–1118. doi:10.1080/03066150.2013.866553. S2CID 154025772.
- Nor-Hisham, Bin Md Saman; Ho, Peter (2016). "A conditional trinity as 'no-go' against non-credible development? Resettlement, customary rights and Malaysia's Kelau Dam". The Journal of Peasant Studies. 43 (6): 1177–1205. doi:10.1080/03066150.2016.1253559. S2CID 157971089.
- Pils, Eva (2016). "Assessing evictions and expropriations in China: Efficiency, credibility and rights". Land Use Policy. Elsevier BV. 58: 437–444. doi:10.1016/j.landusepol.2016.07.015. ISSN 0264-8377.
- Thelen, Kathleen (2002). "The explanatory power of historical institutionalism". In Mayntz, Renate (ed.). Akteure - Mechanismen - Modelle: zur Theoriefähigkeit makro-sozialer Analysen (in German). Frankfurt/Main u.a: Campus-Verl. ISBN 978-3-593-37129-0.
- Ho, Peter (19 December 2013). "In defense of endogenous, spontaneously ordered development: institutional functionalism and Chinese property rights". Journal of Peasant Studies. 40 (6): 1087–1118. doi:10.1080/03066150.2013.866553. S2CID 154025772.
- "Bizarre situatie tijdens sloopproject in Rotterdam". Metronieuws.nl (in Dutch). 2018-09-28. Retrieved 2020-08-08.
- Ho, Peter (2009). "Beyond Development Orthodoxy: Chinese Lessons in Pragmatism and Institutional Change". In Kremer, Monique (ed.). Doing good or doing better: development policies in a globalizing world. Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press. ISBN 978-90-8964-107-6.
- Ho, Peter (2015). "Myths of tenure security and titling: Endogenous, institutional change in China's development". Land Use Policy. 47: 352–364. doi:10.1016/j.landusepol.2015.04.008. ISSN 0264-8377.
- Ho, Peter (2017). "Who owns China's housing? Endogeneity as a lens to understand ambiguities of urban and rural property". Cities. 65: 66–77. doi:10.1016/j.cities.2017.02.004. ISSN 0264-2751.
- Marois, Thomas; Güngen, Ali Rıza (2016). "Credibility and class in the evolution of public banks: the case of Turkey" (PDF). The Journal of Peasant Studies. 43 (6): 1285–1309. doi:10.1080/03066150.2016.1176023. S2CID 155633816.
- Miyamura, Satoshi (2016). "Rethinking labour market institutions in Indian industry: forms, functions and socio-historical contexts" (PDF). The Journal of Peasant Studies. 43 (6): 1262–1284. doi:10.1080/03066150.2016.1192608. S2CID 156917255.
- Monkkonen, Paavo (2016). "Are civil-law notaries rent-seeking monopolists or essential market intermediaries? Endogenous development of a property rights institution in Mexico". The Journal of Peasant Studies. 43 (6): 1224–1248. doi:10.1080/03066150.2016.1216983. PMC 5467891. PMID 28615798.
- Mollinga, Peter P. (2016). "Secure rights and non-credibility: the paradoxical dynamics of canal irrigation in India" (PDF). The Journal of Peasant Studies. 43 (6): 1310–1331. doi:10.1080/03066150.2016.1215304. S2CID 157343250.
- Zhao, Heng; Rokpelnis, Karlis (2016). "Local perceptions of grassland degradation in China: a socio-anthropological reading of endogenous knowledge and institutional credibility". The Journal of Peasant Studies. 43 (6): 1206–1223. doi:10.1080/03066150.2016.1192609. S2CID 157839821.
- L.P. "Autocracy or democracy?". The Economist. Retrieved 2015-06-18.
- OECD. "Issues paper on corruption and economic growth". oecd.org. Retrieved 2015-06-20.
- Zheng, Ying; Ho, Peter (2020). "Unpacking the paradox of "insecure" housing rights in China: Urban residents' perceptions on institutional credibility". Cities. Elsevier BV. 97: 102485. doi:10.1016/j.cities.2019.102485. ISSN 0264-2751. S2CID 213538577.
- Clarke, Donald (2018). "Form and function in China's urban land regime: The irrelevance of "ownership"". Land Use Policy. Elsevier BV. 79: 902–912. doi:10.1016/j.landusepol.2016.11.008. ISSN 0264-8377.
- Aron, J. (2000). "Growth and Institutions: A Review of the Evidence". The World Bank Research Observer. 15 (1): 99–135. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.200.1784. doi:10.1093/wbro/15.1.99. ISSN 0257-3032.
- Agrawal, Arun; Wollenberg, E.; Persha, L. (2014). "Governing agriculture-forest landscapes to achieve climate change mitigation". Global Environmental Change. 29: 270–280. doi:10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2014.10.001. ISSN 0959-3780.
- Dixon, Adam D. (2012-01-19). "Function before form: macro-institutional comparison and the geography of finance". Journal of Economic Geography. 12 (3): 579–600. doi:10.1093/jeg/lbr043. ISSN 1468-2710.
- Chang (2007). Institutional change and economic development. New York, NY: United Nations University Press. ISBN 978-92-808-1143-8.
- Griswold, Delilah (9 July 2015). "With efficacy of property rights, function can be more important than form". Yale Environment Review. Retrieved 18 November 2015.
- Davy, Benjamin (2018). "After form. The credibility thesis meets property theory". Land Use Policy. Elsevier BV. 79: 854–862. doi:10.1016/j.landusepol.2017.02.036. ISSN 0264-8377.
- "Past Recipients of the Kapp Prize". EAEPE. Retrieved 2020-08-09.
- Kung, James Kai-sing; Liu, Shouying (1997). "Farmers' Preferences Regarding Ownership and Land Tenure in Post-Mao China: Unexpected Evidence from Eight Counties". The China Journal. 38 (38): 33–63. doi:10.2307/2950334. JSTOR 2950334. S2CID 144329012. Retrieved 2020-08-09.
- 杨学成; 赵瑞莹; 岳书铭 (2015-09-21). "农村土地关系思考——基于1995~2008年三次山东农户调查". 管理世界 (in Chinese) (7): 53–61. Retrieved 2020-08-09.
- 丰雷; 蒋妍; 叶剑平; 朱可亮 (2015-09-21). "中国农村土地调整制度变迁中的农户态度——基于1999~2010年17省份调查的实证分析". 管理世界 (in Chinese) (7): 44–58. Retrieved 2020-08-09.
- 孔涛; Jonathan; 刘鹏凌 (2015-09-21). "农村承包地调整的实证研究——通过村民小组数据的分析". 农业经济问题 (in Chinese) (11): 87–97. Retrieved 2020-08-09.
- Koroso, Nesru H.; Zevenbergen, Jaap A.; Lengoiboni, Monica (2019). "Land institutions' credibility: Analyzing the role of complementary institutions". Land Use Policy. Elsevier BV. 81: 553–564. doi:10.1016/j.landusepol.2018.11.026. ISSN 0264-8377. S2CID 158979099.
- Ho, Peter (2006). "Credibility of institutions: Forestry, social conflict and titling in China". Land Use Policy. Elsevier BV. 23 (4): 588–603. doi:10.1016/j.landusepol.2005.05.004. ISSN 0264-8377.
- Fold, Niels; Allotey, Albert N.M.; Kalvig, Per; Moeller-Jensen, Lasse (2018). "Grounding institutions through informal practice: Credibility in artisanal mining of aggregates, Ghana". Land Use Policy. Elsevier BV. 79: 922–931. doi:10.1016/j.landusepol.2017.06.022. ISSN 0264-8377.
- Gomes, Sharlene L.; Hermans, Leon M. (2018). "Institutional function and urbanization in Bangladesh: How peri-urban communities respond to changing environments". Land Use Policy. Elsevier BV. 79: 932–941. doi:10.1016/j.landusepol.2017.09.041. ISSN 0264-8377.
- Easthope, Hazel; van den Nouwelant, Ryan; Thompson, Sian (2020). "Apartment ownership around the world: Focusing on credible outcomes rather than ideal systems". Cities. Elsevier BV. 97: 102463. doi:10.1016/j.cities.2019.102463. ISSN 0264-2751. S2CID 214057580.
- Tzfadia, Erez; Meir, Avinoam; Roded, Batya; Atzmon, Eli (2020). "Gray local governance and Israeli Indigenous Bedouin: Credibility, functionality and the politics of refusal". Cities. Elsevier BV. 97: 102484. doi:10.1016/j.cities.2019.102484. ISSN 0264-2751. S2CID 213201709.
- Rogge, Karoline S.; Dütschke, Elisabeth (2018). "What makes them believe in the low-carbon energy transition? Exploring corporate perceptions of the credibility of climate policy mixes". Environmental Science & Policy. Elsevier BV. 87: 74–84. doi:10.1016/j.envsci.2018.05.009. ISSN 1462-9011.
- Wu, Jiayu; Song, Yan; Lin, Jian; He, Qingsong (2018). "Tackling the uncertainty of spatial regulations in China: An institutional analysis of the "multi-plan combination"". Habitat International. Elsevier BV. 78: 1–12. doi:10.1016/j.habitatint.2018.07.002. ISSN 0197-3975.
- Arvanitidis, Paschalis A.; Papagiannitsis, George (2020). "Urban open spaces as a commons: The credibility thesis and common property in a self-governed park of Athens, Greece". Cities. Elsevier BV. 97: 102480. doi:10.1016/j.cities.2019.102480. ISSN 0264-2751. S2CID 213072389.
- Yang, Xiuyun; Ho, Peter (2019). "Mining institutions, contention and credibility: Applying the Conflict Analysis Model to court cases in China". The Extractive Industries and Society. Elsevier BV. 7 (3): 1011–1021. doi:10.1016/j.exis.2019.11.012. ISSN 2214-790X. S2CID 214389217.
- Sun, Li; Ho, Peter (2018). "Formalizing informal homes, a bad idea: The credibility thesis applied to China's "extra-legal" housing" (PDF). Land Use Policy. Elsevier BV. 79: 891–901. doi:10.1016/j.landusepol.2016.10.024. ISSN 0264-8377.
- Zeuthen, Jesper Willaing (2018). "Whose urban development? Changing credibilities, forms and functions of urbanization in Chengdu, China". Land Use Policy. Elsevier BV. 79: 942–951. doi:10.1016/j.landusepol.2017.07.009. ISSN 0264-8377.