Fee-for-service
Fee-for-service (FFS) is a payment model where services are unbundled and paid for separately.
In health care, it gives an incentive for physicians to provide more treatments because payment is dependent on the quantity of care, rather than quality of care. However evidence of the effectiveness of FFS in improving health care quality is mixed, without conclusive proof that these programs either succeed or fail.[1] Similarly, when patients are shielded from paying (cost-sharing) by health insurance coverage, they are incentivized to welcome any medical service that might do some good. Fee-for-services raises costs, and discourages the efficiencies of integrated care. A variety of reform efforts have been attempted, recommended, or initiated to reduce its influence (such as moving towards bundled payments and capitation). In capitation, physicians are not incentivized to perform procedures, including necessary ones, because they are not paid anything extra for performing them.
FFS is the dominant physician payment method in the United States.[2] In the Japanese health care system, FFS is mixed with a nationwide price setting mechanism (all-payer rate setting) to control costs.[3]
Health care
In the health insurance and the health care industries, FFS occurs if doctors and other health care providers receive a fee for each service such as an office visit, test, procedure, or other health care service.[4] Payments are issued only after the services are provided. FFS is potentially inflationary by raising health care costs.[5]
FFS creates a potential financial conflict of interest with patients, as it incentivizes overutilization,[6]—treatments with an inappropriately excessive volume or cost.[7]
FFS does not incentivize physicians to withhold services.[8] If bills are paid under FFS by a third party, patients (along with doctors) have no incentive to consider the cost of treatment.[9] Patients can welcome services under third-party payers because "when people are insulated from the cost of a desirable product or service, they use more."[10]
Evidence suggests primary care physicians paid under a FFS model tend to treat patients with more procedures than those paid under capitation or a salary.[11] FFS incentivizes primary care physicians to invest in radiology clinics and perform physician self-referral to generate income.[12]
While most practices have succumbed to the need to see more patients and increase FFS procedures to maintain revenue, more physicians are looking to alternate practice models as a better solution. In addition to value-based reimbursement models, such as pay-for-performance programs and accountable care organizations, there is a resurgence of interest in concierge and direct-pay practice models.[13] When patients have greater access to their physicians and physicians have more time to spend with patients, utilization of services such as imaging and testing declines.
FFS is a barrier to coordinated care, or integrated care, exemplified by the Mayo Clinic, because it rewards individual clinicians for performing separate treatments.[14][15] FFS also does not pay providers to pay attention to the most costly patients,[16] which could benefit from interventions such as phone calls that can make some hospital stays and 911 calls unnecessary.[16][17] In the US, FFS is the main payment method.[2] Executives regret the changes to managed care, believing that FFS turned "industrious, productivity-oriented physicians into complacent, salaried employees."[2][8] General practitioners have less autonomy after switching from a FFS model to integrated care.[18] Patients, when moved off of a FFS model, may have their choices of physicians restricted, as was done in the Netherlands' attempt to move to co-ordinated care.[18]
When physicians cannot bill for a service, it serves as a disincentive to perform that service if other billable options exist. Electronic referral, when a specialist evaluates medical data (such as laboratory tests or photos) to diagnose a patient instead of seeing the patient in person, would often improve health care quality and lower costs. However, "in the private fee-for-service context, the loss of specialist income is a powerful barrier to e-referral, a barrier that might be overcome if health plans compensated specialists for the time spent handling e-referrals."[19]
In Canada, the proportion of services billed under FFS from 1990 to 2010 shifted substantially.[20] Less care was paid out for patients under 55 while for those over 65, payment for diagnostic services was sharply increased.[20]
Reform
Moving away from FFS towards pay for performance introduces quality and efficiency incentives instead of rewarding quantity alone.[15] In addition to the Mayo Clinic, other health care systems serve as co-ordinated/integrated care alternatives to the FFS model like South Central Pennsylvania's Geisinger Health System whose physicians, residents and fellows are paid a salary with the potential for bonuses depending upon patient performance, Utah's Intermountain Healthcare, the Cleveland Clinic, and Kaiser Permanente.[12] Coordinated care can produce cost savings of about 50% when compared to FFS programs, but long term savings for payers may not exceed 40%.[18]
A goal of accountable care organizations (ACOs), part of the 2010 Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act (PPACA), is to move from FFS to integrated care.[21] ACOs, however, fit largely into a FFS framework and do not abandon the model entirely.[22] That approach suggests policymakers are attempting to avoid provoking public outcry, as happened with managed care in the 1990s by giving providers incentives to give less care.[22] The PPACA aims to first move Medicare away from FFS and then other payers.[23] A Swiss study showed physicians wanted significant pay raises to leave FFS for an integrated care model, and patients wanted lower premiums before they would choose one, results that hint at difficulties for PPACA aims.[18]
In China, where FFS resulted in costly, inefficient, and poor quality health care with a degeneration in medical ethics, reforms have been initiated to realign health care provider incentives.[5] Experimentation with new payment models is ongoing and recommendations include a strengthening of medical ethics, alterations to provider's profit motives, and, if hospitals retain their profit motive, segregating physicians from the goal of profit.[5]
In the US, a 1990s move from FFS to pure capitation provoked a backlash from patients and health care providers.[15] Pure capitation pays only a set fee per patient, regardless of sickness, giving physicians an incentive to avoid the most costly patients.[24] To avoid the pitfalls of FFS and pure capitation, models of episode-of-care payment and comprehensive care payment have been proposed.[24] In 2009, Massachusetts, with the highest health care costs in the country, had a group of ten health care experts who worked under legislative mandate to come up with a plan to tackle costs (the Massachusetts Payment Reform Commission); they unanimously concluded the FFS model must be done away with.[16] Their plan included a move away from FFS to a global payment system that had similarities to a capitated system.[16]
In 2014, Maryland set up an independent commission which created a fixed revenue system, or global budget for the state's hospitals. Both public and private insurers pay into a common fund. Each hospital has a stable yearly income which it can use to plan. Budgets were originally based on the number of patients and procedures reported in 2013, with annual adjustments for inflation and population change. Going forward, it is to a hospital's benefit to avoid unnecessary procedures and to adopt preventive programs that reduce chronic illness and re-admissions. In its first five years, Maryland's new payment system saved an estimated $1.4 billion in Medicare costs compared to other states. In addition, rates of preventable hospital-acquired illness fell.[25]
An even more striking difference was observed during the COVID-19 pandemic as fee-for-service hospitals provided less of the elective services that they depended on for funding. An assessment of the Financial Effects of COVID-19: Hospital Outlook for the Remainder of 2021 predicted that hospital income could remain as much as 80 percent lower than pre-pandemic levels. In contrast, outpatient hospital revenue fell only 14.6 percent and inpatient revenue by 1.6 percent in Maryland's hospitals, looking at the period from January–July in 2019 and 2020.[25][26]
Medicare in the US is a FFS program.[27] The Medicare Payment Advisory Commission (MedPAC), in its mid-2011 report to Congress, called for a mechanism so that Medicare beneficiaries would have disincentives to undergo unnecessary care.[28]
Patents
The United States Patent and Trademark Office operates on a FFS model.[29]
Real estate
In real estate, the fee-for-service model of paying a broker provides an alternative to paying commission. In the fee-for service pricing model, a broker may charge for showing trips or other services.[30]
References
- Ryan, Andrew M.; Werner, Rachel M. (October 9, 2013). "Doubts About Pay-for-Performance in Health Care". Harvard Business Review – via hbr.org.
- Robert A. Berenson & Eugene C. Rich (June 2010). "US approaches to physician payment: the deconstruction of primary care". Journal of General Internal Medicine. 25 (6): 613–618. doi:10.1007/s11606-010-1295-z. PMC 2869428. PMID 20467910.
- "Sick around the world". Frontline. April 15, 2008. 17 minutes in. PBS.
- FEHB Glossary. Retrieved May 31, 2006.
- Winnie Chi-Man Yip, William Hsiao, Qingyue Meng, Wen Chen & Xiaoming Sun (March 2010). "Realignment of incentives for health-care providers in China". The Lancet. 375 (9720): 1120–1130. doi:10.1016/S0140-6736(10)60063-3. PMID 20346818. S2CID 19766054.
{{cite journal}}
: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link) - Ronald M. Green (July–August 1990). "Medical joint-venturing: An ethical perspective". Hastings Center Report. 20 (4): 22–6. doi:10.2307/3562762. JSTOR 3562762. PMID 2211082.
- Ezekiel J. Emanuel & Victor R. Fuchs (June 2008). "The perfect storm of overutilization" (PDF). JAMA: The Journal of the American Medical Association. 299 (23): 2789–2791. doi:10.1001/jama.299.23.2789. PMID 18560006. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2009-09-02.
- Chernew ME (2010). "Reforming payment for health care services: comment on "physicians' opinions about reforming reimbursement"". Arch Intern Med. 170 (19): 1742–4. doi:10.1001/archinternmed.2010.377. PMID 20975021.
- Victor R. Fuchs (December 2009). "Eliminating 'waste' in health care". JAMA: The Journal of the American Medical Association. 302 (22): 2481–2482. doi:10.1001/jama.2009.1821. PMID 19996406.
- Merrill Matthews; Mark Litow (July 11, 2011). "Why Medicare Patients See the Doctor Too Much". The Wall Street Journal. Retrieved July 22, 2011.
- Gosden T, Forland F, Kristiansen IS, et al. (2000). "Capitation, salary, fee-for-service and mixed systems of payment: effects on the behaviour of primary care physicians". Cochrane Database Syst Rev. 2011 (3): CD002215. doi:10.1002/14651858.CD002215. PMC 9879313. PMID 10908531.
- Jeffery Kluger (October 26, 2009). "A Healthier Way to Pay Doctors". TIME. 174 (16): 36–40. PMID 19873802. Archived from the original on October 19, 2009.
- "Healthcare Reform Influencing Physicians' Career Choices" Archived 2012-09-21 at the Wayback Machine Aubrey Westgate, Physicians Practice, September 2012.
- Lawrence, David (2005). Building a Better Delivery System: A New Engineering/Health Care Partnership – Bridging the Quality Chasm (PDF). Washington, DC: National Academy of Sciences. p. 99. ISBN 978-0-309-65406-7.
- Karen Davis (March 2007). "Paying for care episodes and care coordination". The New England Journal of Medicine. 356 (11): 1166–1168. doi:10.1056/NEJMe078007. PMID 17360996.
- Richard Knox (August 5, 2009). "To Lower Costs, Mass. May Restructure Doctor Pay". Morning Edition. NPR. Retrieved June 26, 2011.
- Atul Gawande (January 24, 2011). "The Hot Spotters: Can we lower medical costs by giving the neediest patients better care?". The New Yorker. Retrieved June 26, 2011.
- Peter Zweifel (March 2011). "Swiss experiment shows physicians, consumers want significant compensation to embrace coordinated care". Health Affairs. 30 (3): 510–518. doi:10.1377/hlthaff.2010.0954. PMID 21383370.
- Thomas Bodenheimer (March 2008). "Coordinating care – a perilous journey through the health care system". The New England Journal of Medicine. 358 (10): 1064–1071. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.527.4412. doi:10.1056/NEJMhpr0706165. PMID 18322289.
- Rachel Mendleson (October 25, 2010). "The Worst-Run Industry in Canada: Health Care". Canadian Business. 83 (17). Archived from the original on November 8, 2012. Retrieved June 27, 2011.
- Phil Galewitz; Jordan Rau; Bara Vaida (March 31, 2011). "'Accountable care' expected to save millions for Medicare". Kaiser Health News. McClatchy. Retrieved June 26, 2011.
- John K. Iglehart (April 2011). "The ACO regulations – some answers, more questions". The New England Journal of Medicine. 364 (17): e35. doi:10.1056/NEJMp1103603. PMID 21488758.
- Kenneth E. Thorpe & Lydia L. Ogden (June 2010). "Analysis & commentary. The foundation that health reform lays for improved payment, care coordination, and prevention". Health Affairs. 29 (6): 1183–1187. doi:10.1377/hlthaff.2010.0415. PMID 20530352.
- Harold D. Miller (September–October 2009). "From volume to value: better ways to pay for health care". Health Affairs. 28 (5): 1418–1428. doi:10.1377/hlthaff.28.5.1418. PMID 19738259.
- Colmers, John; Glied, Sherry (1 November 2021). "Let's change how we pay for hospitals". Knowable Magazine. doi:10.1146/knowable-102921-1. S2CID 240472969. Retrieved 9 November 2021.
- "Financial Effects of COVID-19: Hospital Outlook for the Remainder of 2021". American Hospital Association. September 2021. Retrieved 9 November 2021.
- Peter B. Bach (January 2007). "Costs of cancer care: a view from the centers for Medicare and Medicaid services". Journal of Clinical Oncology. 25 (2): 187–190. doi:10.1200/JCO.2006.08.6116. PMID 17210938.
- "Medicare Options In Biden Budget Talks Get Boost". NPR. The Associated Press. June 15, 2011. Retrieved June 26, 2011.
- "Report on Departments of Commerce and Justice, Science, and Related Agencies Appropriations Bill, 2009". United States Senate Committee on Appropriations. June 23, 2008. Archived from the original on May 7, 2009. Retrieved July 4, 2011.
As a fee for service agency the USPTO operates in a business like model.
- ABout.com Real Estate Business definitions http://realestate.about.com/od/df/g/deffeeforsvc.htm