Quantitative easing

Quantitative easing (QE) is a monetary policy action where a central bank purchases predetermined amounts of government bonds or other financial assets in order to stimulate economic activity.[1] Quantitative easing is a novel form of monetary policy that came into wide application after the financial crisis of 20072008.[2][3] It is used to mitigate an economic recession when inflation is very low or negative, making standard monetary policy ineffective. Quantitative tightening (QT) does the opposite, where for monetary policy reasons, a central bank sells off some portion of its holdings of government bonds or other financial assets.

Similar to conventional open-market operations used to implement monetary policy, a central bank implements quantitative easing by buying financial assets from commercial banks and other financial institutions, thus raising the prices of those financial assets and lowering their yield, while simultaneously increasing the money supply. However, in contrast to normal policy, quantitative easing usually involves the purchase of riskier or longer-term assets (rather than short-term government bonds) of predetermined amounts at a large scale, over a pre-committed period of time.[4][5]

Central banks usually resort to quantitative easing when their nominal interest rate target approaches or reaches zero. Very low interest rates induce a liquidity trap, a situation where people prefer to hold cash or very liquid assets, given the low returns on other financial assets. This makes it difficult for interest rates to go below zero; monetary authorities may then use quantitative easing to further stimulate the economy rather than trying to lower the interest rate further.

Quantitative easing can help bring the economy out of recession[6] and help ensure that inflation does not fall below the central bank's inflation target.[7] However QE programmes are also criticized for their side-effects and risks, which include the policy being more effective than intended in acting against deflation (leading to higher inflation in the longer term), or not being effective enough if banks remain reluctant to lend and potential borrowers are unwilling to borrow. Quantitative easing has also been criticized for raising financial asset prices, contributing to inequality.[8] Quantitative easing was undertaken by some major central banks worldwide following the global financial crisis of 20072008, and again in response to the COVID-19 pandemic.[9]

Process and benefits

Standard central bank monetary policies are usually enacted by buying or selling government bonds on the open market to reach a desired target for the interbank interest rate. However, if a recession or depression continues even when a central bank has lowered interest rates targets to nearly zero, the central bank can no longer lower interest rates — a situation known as the liquidity trap. The central bank may then attempt to stimulate the economy by implementing quantitative easing, that is, by buying financial assets without reference to interest rates. This policy is sometimes described as a last resort to stimulate the economy.[10][11]

A central bank enacts quantitative easing by purchasing, regardless of interest rates, a predetermined quantity of bonds or other financial assets on financial markets from private financial institutions.[12][13] This action increases the excess reserves that banks hold. The goal of this policy is to ease financial conditions, increase market liquidity, and encourage private bank lending.

Quantitative easing affects the economy through several channels:[14]

  • Credit channel: By providing liquidity in the banking sector, QE makes it easier and cheaper for banks to extend loans to companies and households, thus stimulating credit growth. Additionally, if the central bank also purchases financial instruments that are riskier than government bonds (such as corporate bonds), it can also increase the price and lower the interest yield of these riskier assets.
  • Portfolio rebalancing: By enacting QE, the central bank withdraws an important part of the safe assets from the market onto its own balance sheet, which may result in private investors turning to other financial securities. Because of the relative lack of government bonds, investors are forced to "rebalance their portfolios" into other assets. Additionally, if the central bank also purchases financial instruments that are riskier than government bonds, it can also lower the interest yield of those assets (as those assets are more scarce in the market, and thus their prices go up correspondingly).[15]
  • Exchange rate: Because it increases the money supply and lowers the yield of financial assets, QE tends to depreciate a country's exchange rates relative to other currencies, through the interest rate mechanism.[16] Lower interest rates lead to a capital outflow from a country, thereby reducing foreign demand for a country's money, leading to a weaker currency. This increases demand for exports, and directly benefits exporters and export industries in the country.
  • Fiscal effect: By lowering yields on sovereign bonds, QE makes it cheaper for governments to borrow on financial markets, which may empower the government to provide fiscal stimulus to the economy. Quantitative easing can be viewed as a debt refinancing operation of the "consolidated government" (the government including the central bank), whereby the consolidated government, via the central bank, retires government debt securities and refinances them into central bank reserves.
  • Boosting asset prices: When a central bank buys government bonds from a pension fund, the pension fund, rather than hold on to this money, might invest it in financial assets, such as shares, that gives it a higher return. And when demand for financial assets is high, the value of these assets increases. This makes businesses and households holding shares wealthier – making them more likely to spend more, boosting economic activity.
  • Signalling effect: Some economists argue that QE's main impact is due to its effect on the psychology of the markets, by signaling that the central bank will take extraordinary measures to facilitate economic recovery. For instance, it has been observed that most of the effect of QE in the Eurozone on bond yields happened between the date of the announcement of QE and the actual start of the purchases by the ECB.

History

The Bank of Japan introduced QE from March 19, 2001, until March 2006, after having introduced negative interest rates in 1999. Most western central banks adopted similar policies in the aftermath of the great financial crisis of 2008.[17]

Precedents

A policy similar to quantitative easing had been implemented within the Roman Empire as a response to a financial crisis in 33 A.D.[18]

The US Federal Reserve belatedly implemented policies similar to the recent quantitative easing during the Great Depression of the 1930s.[19][20] Specifically, banks' excess reserves exceeded 6 percent in 1940, whereas they vanished during the entire postwar period until 2008.[21] Despite this fact, many commentators called the scope of the Federal Reserve quantitative easing program after the 2008 crisis "unprecedented".[22][23][24]

Japan (2001–2006)

A policy termed "quantitative easing" (量的緩和, ryōteki kanwa, from 量的 "quantitative" + 緩和 "easing")[25] was first used by the Bank of Japan (BoJ) to fight domestic deflation in the early 2000s.[26][27] The BOJ had maintained short-term interest rates at close to zero since 1999. The Bank of Japan had for many years, and as late as February 2001, stated that "quantitative easing ... is not effective" and rejected its use for monetary policy.[28]

The Bank of Japan adopted quantitative easing on 19 March 2001.[29][30] Under quantitative easing, the BOJ flooded commercial banks with excess liquidity to promote private lending, leaving them with large stocks of excess reserves and therefore little risk of a liquidity shortage.[31] The BOJ accomplished this by buying more government bonds than would be required to set the interest rate to zero. It later also bought asset-backed securities and equities and extended the terms of its commercial paper-purchasing operation.[32] The BOJ increased commercial bank current account balances from ¥5 trillion to ¥35 trillion (approximately US$300 billion) over a four-year period starting in March 2001. The BOJ also tripled the quantity of long-term Japan government bonds it could purchase on a monthly basis. However, the seven-fold increase notwithstanding, current account balances (essentially central bank reserves) being just one (usually relatively small) component of the liability side of a central bank's balance sheet (the main one being banknotes), the resulting peak increase in the BOJ's balance sheet was modest, compared to later actions by other central banks. The Bank of Japan phased out the QE policy in March 2006.[33]

After 2007

After the financial crisis of 20072008, policies similar to those undertaken by Japan were used by the United States, the United Kingdom, and the Eurozone. Quantitative easing was used by these countries because their risk-free short-term nominal interest rates (termed the federal funds rate in the US, or the official bank rate in the UK) were either at or close to zero. According to Thomas Oatley, "QE has been the central pillar of post-crisis economic policy."[3]

During the peak of the financial crisis in 2008, the US Federal Reserve expanded its balance sheet dramatically by adding new assets and new liabilities without "sterilizing" these by corresponding subtractions. In the same period, the United Kingdom also used quantitative easing as an additional arm of its monetary policy to alleviate its financial crisis.[34][35][36]

United States

Federal Reserve holdings of treasury notes (blue) and mortgage-backed securities (red)
   10 Year Treasury Bond
   2 Year Treasury Bond
   3 month Treasury Bond
   Effective Federal Funds Rate
   CPI inflation year/year
  Recessions
(Percent change from a year earlier)
  CPI
  Core CPI

The U.S. Federal Reserve System held between $700 billion and $800 billion of Treasury notes on its balance sheet before the recession.

November 2008: QE1. In late November 2008, the Federal Reserve started buying $600 billion in mortgage-backed securities.[37] By March 2009, it held $1.75 trillion of bank debt, mortgage-backed securities, and Treasury notes; this amount reached a peak of $2.1 trillion in June 2010. Further purchases were halted as the economy started to improve, but resumed in August 2010 when the Fed decided the economy was not growing robustly. After the halt in June, holdings started falling naturally as debt matured and were projected to fall to $1.7 trillion by 2012. The Fed's revised goal became to keep holdings at $2.054 trillion. To maintain that level, the Fed bought $30 billion in two- to ten-year Treasury notes every month.[38]

November 2010: QE2. In November 2010, the Fed announced a second round of quantitative easing, buying $600 billion of Treasury securities by the end of the second quarter of 2011.[39][40] The expression "QE2" became a ubiquitous nickname in 2010, used to refer to this second round of quantitative easing by US central banks.[41] Retrospectively, the round of quantitative easing preceding QE2 was called "QE1".[42][43]

September 2012: QE3. A third round of quantitative easing, "QE3", was announced on 13 September 2012. In an 11–1 vote, the Federal Reserve decided to launch a new $40 billion per month, open-ended bond purchasing program of agency mortgage-backed securities. Additionally, the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) announced that it would likely maintain the federal funds rate near zero "at least through 2015".[44][45] According to NASDAQ.com, this is effectively a stimulus program that allows the Federal Reserve to relieve $40 billion per month of commercial housing market debt risk.[46] Because of its open-ended nature, QE3 has earned the popular nickname of "QE-Infinity".[47] On 12 December 2012, the FOMC announced an increase in the amount of open-ended purchases from $40 billion to $85 billion per month.[48]

On 19 June 2013, Ben Bernanke announced a "tapering" of some of the Fed's QE policies contingent upon continued positive economic data. Specifically, he said that the Fed could scale back its bond purchases from $85 billion to $65 billion a month during the upcoming September 2013 policy meeting.[49][50] He also suggested that the bond-buying program could wrap up by mid-2014.[51] While Bernanke did not announce an interest rate hike, he suggested that if inflation followed a 2% target rate and unemployment decreased to 6.5%, the Fed would likely start raising rates. The stock markets dropped by approximately 4.3% over the three trading days following Bernanke's announcement, with the Dow Jones dropping 659 points between 19 and 24 June, closing at 14,660 at the end of the day on 24 June.[52] On 18 September 2013, the Fed decided to hold off on scaling back its bond-buying program,[53] and announced in December 2013 that it would begin to taper its purchases in January 2014.[54] Purchases were halted on 29 October 2014[55] after accumulating $4.5 trillion in assets.[56]

March 2020: QE4.

Increase in US Federal Reserve assets in response to COVID-19 pandemic[57]

The Federal Reserve began conducting its fourth quantitative easing operation since the 2008 financial crisis; on 15 March 2020, it announced approximately $700 billion in new quantitative easing via asset purchases to support US liquidity in response to the COVID-19 pandemic.[58] As of mid-summer 2020 this resulted in an additional $2 trillion in assets on the books of the Federal Reserve.[59]

United Kingdom

Immediate and delayed effects of quantitative easing[60]

The Bank of England's QE programme commenced in March 2009, when it purchased around £165 billion in assets as of September 2009 and around £175 billion in assets by the end of October 2009.[61] Five further tranches of bond purchases between 2009 and November 2020 brought the peak QE total to £895 billion.[62]

The Bank imposed a number of constraints on the QE policy, namely, that it would not buy more than 70% of any issue of government debt; and that it would only buy traditional (non-index-linked) debt, with a maturity of more than three years.[63] Originally, the bonds eligible for purchase were limited to UK government debt, but this was later relaxed to include high quality commercial bonds.[64]

QE was primarily designed as an instrument of monetary policy. The mechanism required the Bank of England to purchase government bonds on the secondary market, financed by the creation of new central bank money. This would have the effect of increasing the asset prices of the bonds purchased, thereby lowering yields and dampening longer term interest rates and making it cheaper for businesses to raise capital.[65] The aim of the policy was initially to ease liquidity constraints in the sterling reserves system, but evolved into a wider policy to provide economic stimulus. Another side effect is that investors will switch to other investments, such as shares, boosting their price and thus encouraging consumption.[66] In 2012 the Bank estimated that quantitative easing had benefited households differentially according to the assets they hold; richer households have more assets.[67]

In February 2022 the Bank of England announced its intention to commence winding down the QE portfolio.[68] Initially this would be achieved by not replacing tranches of maturing bonds, and would later be accelerated through active bond sales.

In August 2022 the Bank of England reiterated its intention to accelerate the QE wind down through active bond sales. This policy was affirmed in an exchange of letters between the Bank of England and the UK Chancellor of the Exchequer in September 2022.[69] Between February 2022 and September 2022, a total of £37.1bn of government bonds matured, reducing the outstanding stock from £875.0bn at the end of 2021 to £837.9bn. In addition, a total of £1.1bn of corporate bonds matured, reducing the stock from £20.0bn to £18.9bn, with sales of the remaining stock planned to begin on 27 September.

On 28 September 2022 the Bank of England issued a Market Notice announcing its intention to "carry out purchases of long dated gilts in a temporary and targeted way".[70] This was in response to market conditions in which the sterling exchange rate and bond asset pricing were significantly disrupted following a UK government fiscal statement.[71] The Bank stated its announcement would apply to conventional gilts of residual maturity greater than 20 years in the secondary market. The existing constraints applicable to QE bond purchases would continue to apply. The funding of the purchases would be met from central bank reserves, but would be segregated in a different portfolio from existing asset purchases. The Bank also announced that its annual £80bn target to reduce the existing QE portfolio remained unchanged but, in the light of current market conditions, the beginning of gilt sale operations would be postponed to 31 October 2022.[72]

Eurozone

The European Central Bank engaged in large-scale purchase of covered bonds in May 2009,[73] and purchased around €250 billion worth of sovereign bonds from targeted member states in 2010 and 2011 (the SMP Programme). However, until 2015 the ECB refused to openly admit they were doing quantitative easing.

In a dramatic change of policy, following the new Jackson Hole Consensus, on 22 January 2015 Mario Draghi, President of the European Central Bank, announced an "expanded asset purchase programme", where €60 billion per month of euro-area bonds from central governments, agencies and European institutions would be bought.[74]

Beginning in March 2015, the stimulus was planned to last until September 2016 at the earliest with a total QE of at least €1.1 trillion. Mario Draghi announced the programme would continue: "until we see a continued adjustment in the path of inflation", referring to the ECB's need to combat the growing threat of deflation across the eurozone in early 2015.[75][76]

In March 2016, the ECB increased its monthly bond purchases to €80 billion from €60 billion and started to include corporate bonds under the asset purchasing programme and announced new ultra-cheap four-year loans to banks. From November 2019, the ECB resumed buying up eurozone government bonds at a rate of €20 billion in an effort to encourage governments to borrow more and spend in domestic investment projects.[77] In March 2020, to help the economy absorb the shock of the COVID-19 crisis, the ECB announced a €750 billion Pandemic Emergency Purchase Programme (PEPP).[78] The aim of the stimulus package (PEPP) was to lower borrowing costs and increase lending in the euro area.[79]

Switzerland

At the beginning of 2013, the Swiss National Bank had the largest balance sheet relative to the size of its economy. It was responsible for, at close to 100% of Switzerland's national output. A total of 12% of its reserves were in foreign equities. By contrast, the US Federal Reserve's holdings equalled about 20% of US GDP, while the European Central Bank's assets were worth 30% of GDP.[80]

The SNB's balance sheet has increased massively due to its QE programme, to the extent that in December 2020, the US treasury accused Switzerland of being a "currency manipulator". The US administration recommended Switzerland to increase the retirement age for Swiss workers to reduce saving assets by the Swiss Social Security administration, in order to boost domestic demand and reduce the necessity to maintain QE to stabilize the parity between the dollar and the Swiss franc.[81]

Sweden

Sveriges Riksbank launched quantitative easing in February 2015, announcing government bond purchases of nearly US$1.2 billion.[82] The annualised inflation rate in January 2015 was -0.3%, and the bank implied that Sweden's economy could slide into deflation.[82]

Japan after 2007 and Abenomics

In early October 2010, the Bank of Japan (BOJ) announced that it would examine the purchase of ¥5 trillion (US$60 billion) in assets. This was an attempt to push down the value of the yen against the US dollar to stimulate the domestic economy by making Japanese exports cheaper; however, it was ineffective.[83]

On 4 August 2011 the BOJ announced a unilateral move to increase the commercial bank current account balance from ¥40 trillion (US$504 billion) to a total of ¥50 trillion (US$630 billion).[84][85] In October 2011, the bank expanded its asset purchase program by ¥5 trillion ($66bn) to a total of ¥55 trillion.[86]

On 4 April 2013, the Bank of Japan announced that it would expand its asset purchase program by ¥60 trillion to ¥70 trillion per year.[87] The bank hoped to banish deflation and achieve an inflation rate of 2% within two years. This would be achieved through a QE programme worth US$1.4 trillion, an amount so large it is expected to double the money supply.[88] This policy has been named Abenomics, a portmanteau of economic policies from Shinzō Abe, the former Prime Minister of Japan.

On 31 October 2014, the BOJ announced the expansion of its bond buying program, to purchase ¥80 trillion of bonds a year.[89]

In addition to purchases of bonds, Governor Masaaki Shirakawa also directed the BOJ to begin purchasing corporate shares as well as debt securities in October 2010. The BOJ came up with a policy to purchase index ETFs as part of the 2010 Comprehensive Monetary Easing program, which initially placed a cap of ¥450 billion shares with a termination in December 2011. However, later Governor Haruhiko Kuroda replaced the program with the Quantitative and Qualitative Monetary Easing policy which empowered the BOJ to buy ETFs with no cap or termination date, with an increased annual target of ¥1 trillion. The cap was raised multiple times to over ¥19 trillion by March 2018. And in March 16, 2020, following the Covid pandemic, the BOJ doubled its annual ETF purchase target to ¥12 trillion.[90]

Effectiveness of QE

The effectiveness of quantitative easing is the subject of an intense dispute among researchers as it is difficult to separate the effect of quantitative easing from other contemporaneous economic and policy measures, such as negative rates.

Former Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan calculated that as of July 2012, there was "very little impact on the economy".[91] Bank deposits in the Fed increased by nearly $4 trillion during QE1-3, closely tracking Fed bond purchases. A different assessment has been offered by Federal Reserve Governor Jeremy Stein, who has said that measures of quantitative easing such as large-scale asset purchases "have played a significant role in supporting economic activity".[92]

While the literature on the topic has grown over time, it has also been shown that central banks' own research on the effectiveness of quantitative easing tends to be optimistic in comparison to research by independent researchers,[93] which could indicate a conflict of interest or cognitive bias in central bank research.

Several studies published in the aftermath of the crisis found that quantitative easing in the US has effectively contributed to lower long term interest rates on a variety of securities as well as lower credit risk. This boosted GDP growth and modestly increased inflation.[94][95][96][97][98][99] A predictable but unintended consequence of the lower interest rates was to drive investment capital into equities, thereby inflating the value of equities relative to the value of goods and services, and increasing the wealth gap between the wealthy and working class.

In the Eurozone, studies have shown that QE successfully averted deflationary spirals in 2013–2014, and prevented the widening of bond yield spreads between member states.[100] QE also helped reduce bank lending cost.[101] However, the real effect of QE on GDP and inflation remained modest[102][103] and very heterogeneous depending on methodologies used in research studies, which find on GDP comprised between 0.2% and 1.5% and between 0.1 and 1.4% on inflation. Model-based studies tend to find a higher impact than empirical ones.

In Japan, focusing on equity purchases, studies have shown that QE successfully boosted stock prices,[104][90] but appear to have not been successful in stimulating corporate investment.[90]

Risks and side-effects

Quantitative easing may cause higher inflation than desired if the amount of easing required is overestimated and too much money is created by the purchase of liquid assets.[105] On the other hand, QE can fail to spur demand if banks remain reluctant to lend money to businesses and households. Even then, QE can still ease the process of deleveraging as it lowers yields. However, there is a time lag between monetary growth and inflation; inflationary pressures associated with money growth from QE could build before the central bank acts to counter them.[106] Inflationary risks are mitigated if the system's economy outgrows the pace of the increase of the money supply from the easing. If production in an economy increases because of the increased money supply, the value of a unit of currency may also increase, even though there is more currency available. For example, if a nation's economy were to spur a significant increase in output at a rate at least as high as the amount of debt monetized the inflationary pressures would be equalized. This can only happen if member banks actually lend the excess money out instead of hoarding the extra cash. During times of high economic output, the central bank always has the option of restoring reserves to higher levels through raising interest rates or other means, effectively reversing the easing steps taken.

Economists such as John Taylor[107] believe that quantitative easing creates unpredictability. Since the increase in bank reserves may not immediately increase the money supply if held as excess reserves, the increased reserves create the danger that inflation may eventually result when the reserves are loaned out.[108]

QE benefits debtors; since the interest rate has fallen, there is less money to be repaid. However, it directly harms creditors as they earn less money from lower interest rates. Devaluation of a currency also directly harms importers and consumers, as the cost of imported goods is inflated by the devaluation of the currency.[109]

Impact on savings and pensions

In the European Union, World Pensions Council (WPC) financial economists have also argued that artificially low government bond interest rates induced by QE will have an adverse impact on the underfunding condition of pension funds, since "without returns that outstrip inflation, pension investors face the real value of their savings declining rather than ratcheting up over the next few years".[110][111] In addition to this, low or negative interest rates create disincentives for saving.[112] In a way this is an intended effect, since QE is intended to spur consumer spending.

Effects on climate change

In Europe, central banks operating corporate quantitative easing (i.e., QE programmes that include corporate bonds) such as the European Central Bank or the Swiss National Bank, have been increasingly criticized by NGOs[113] for not taking into account the climate impact of the companies issuing the bonds.[114][115][116][117] In effect, Corporate QE programmes are perceived as indirect subsidy to polluting companies. The European Parliament has also joined the criticism by adopting several resolutions on the matter, and has repeatedly called on the ECB to reflect climate change considerations in its policies.[118][119]

Central banks have usually responded by arguing they had to follow the principle of "market neutrality"[120] and should therefore refrain from making discretionary choices when selecting bonds on the market. The notion that central banks can be market neutral is contested, as central banks always make choices that are not neutral for financial markets when implementing monetary policy.[121] Furthermore, research has demonstrated that, in the case of the ECB's corporate bond purchase programme, the principle of market neutrality is not a practical reality, as the ECB's purchases are concentrated on economic sectors that are not representative of the wider economy, and tend to be skewed towards carbon-intensive firms.[122]

Following this criticism, in 2020, several top level ECB policymaker such as Christine Lagarde,[123] Isabel Schnabel, Frank Elderson[124] and others have pointed out the contradiction in the market neutrality logic. In particular, Schnabel argued that "In the presence of market failures, market neutrality may not be the appropriate benchmark for a central bank when the market by itself is not achieving efficient outcomes"[125]

Since 2020, several central banks (including the ECB, Bank of England and the Swedish central banks) have announced their intention to incorporate climate criteria in their QE programmes.[126] The Network for Greening the Financial System has identified different possible measures to align central banks' collateral frameworks and QE with climate objectives.[127]

Increased income and wealth inequality

Critics frequently point to the redistributive effects of quantitative easing. For instance, British Prime Minister Theresa May openly criticized QE in July 2016 for its regressive effects: "Monetary policy – in the form of super-low interest rates and quantitative easing – has helped those on the property ladder at the expense of those who can't afford to own their own home."[128] Dhaval Joshi of BCA Research wrote that "QE cash ends up overwhelmingly in profits, thereby exacerbating already extreme income inequality and the consequent social tensions that arise from it".[129] Anthony Randazzo of the Reason Foundation wrote that QE "is fundamentally a regressive redistribution program that has been boosting wealth for those already engaged in the financial sector or those who already own homes, but passing little along to the rest of the economy. It is a primary driver of income inequality".[129]

Those criticisms are partly based on some evidence provided by central banks themselves. In 2012, a Bank of England report[130] showed that its quantitative easing policies had benefited mainly the wealthy, and that 40% of those gains went to the richest 5% of British households.[129][131]

In May 2013, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas President Richard Fisher said that cheap money has made rich people richer, but has not done quite as much for working Americans.[132]

Answering similar criticisms expressed by MEP Molly Scott Cato, the President of the ECB Mario Draghi once declared:[133]

Some of these policies may, on the one hand, increase inequality but, on the other hand, if we ask ourselves what the major source of inequality is, the answer would be unemployment. So, to the extent that these policies help – and they are helping on that front – then certainly an accommodative monetary policy is better in the present situation than a restrictive monetary policy.

In July 2018, the ECB published a study[134] showing that its QE programme increased the net wealth of the poorest fifth of the population by 2.5 percent, compared with just 1.0 percent for the richest fifth. The study's credibility was however contested.[135][136]

International spillovers for BRICs and emerging economies

Quantitative easing (QE) policies can have a profound effect on Forex rates, since it changes the supply of one currency compared to another. For instance, if both the US and Europe are using quantitative easing to the same degree then the currency pair of US/EUR may not fluctuate. However, if the US treasury uses QE to a higher degree, as evidenced in the increased purchase of securities during an economic crisis, but India does not, then the value of the USD will decrease relative to the Indian rupee. As a result, quantitative easing has the same effect as purchasing foreign currencies, effectively manipulating the value of one currency compared to another.[137][138]

BRIC countries have criticized the QE carried out by the central banks of developed nations. They share the argument that such actions amount to protectionism and competitive devaluation. As net exporters whose currencies are partially pegged to the dollar, they protest that QE causes inflation to rise in their countries and penalizes their industries.[139][140][141][142]

In a joint statement leaders of Russia, Brazil, India, China and South Africa, collectively BRICS, have condemned the policies of western economies saying "It is critical for advanced economies to adopt responsible macro-economic and financial policies, avoid creating excessive liquidity and undertake structural reforms to lift growth" as written in the Telegraph.[143]

According to Bloomberg reporter David Lynch, the new money from quantitative easing could be used by the banks to invest in emerging markets, commodity-based economies, commodities themselves, and non-local opportunities rather than to lend to local businesses that are having difficulty getting loans.[144]

Moral hazard

Another criticism prevalent in Europe,[145] is that QE creates moral hazard for governments. Central banks’ purchases of government securities artificially depress the cost of borrowing. Normally, governments issuing additional debt see their borrowing costs rise, which discourages them from overdoing it. In particular, market discipline in the form of higher interest rates will cause a government like Italy's, tempted to increase deficit spending, to think twice. Not so, however, when the central bank acts as bond buyer of last resort and is prepared to purchase government securities without limit. In such circumstances, market discipline will be incapacitated.

Reputational risks

Richard W. Fisher, president of the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, warned in 2010 that QE carries "the risk of being perceived as embarking on the slippery slope of debt monetization. We know that once a central bank is perceived as targeting government debt yields[112] at a time of persistent budget deficits, concern about debt monetization quickly arises." Later in the same speech, he stated that the Fed is monetizing the government debt: "The math of this new exercise is readily transparent: The Federal Reserve will buy $110 billion a month in Treasuries, an amount that, annualized, represents the projected deficit of the federal government for next year. For the next eight months, the nation's central bank will be monetizing the federal debt."[146]

Ben Bernanke remarked in 2002 that the US government had a technology called the printing press (or, today, its electronic equivalent), so that if rates reached zero and deflation threatened, the government could always act to ensure deflation was prevented. He said, however, that the government would not print money and distribute it "willy nilly" but would rather focus its efforts in certain areas (e.g., buying federal agency debt securities and mortgage-backed securities).[147][148]

According to economist Robert McTeer, former president of the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, there is nothing wrong with printing money during a recession, and quantitative easing is different from traditional monetary policy "only in its magnitude and pre-announcement of amount and timing".[4][5]

Alternative policies

QE for the people

In response to concerns that QE is failing to create sufficient demand, particularly in the Eurozone, some have called for "QE for the people" or "helicopter money". Instead of buying government bonds or other securities by creating bank reserves, as the Federal Reserve and Bank of England have done, some suggest that central banks could make payments directly to households (in a similar fashion as Milton Friedman's helicopter money).[149]

Economists Mark Blyth and Eric Lonergan argue in Foreign Affairs that this is the most effective solution for the Eurozone, particularly given the restrictions on fiscal policy.[150] They argue that based on the evidence from tax rebates in the United States, less than 5% of GDP transferred by the ECB to the household sector in the Eurozone would suffice to generate a recovery, a fraction of what it intends to be done under standard QE. Oxford economist John Muellbauer has suggested that this could be legally implemented using the electoral register.[151]

On 27 March 2015, 19 economists including Steve Keen, Ann Pettifor, Robert Skidelsky, and Guy Standing have signed a letter to the Financial Times calling on the European Central Bank to adopt a more direct approach to its quantitative easing plan announced earlier in February.[152] In August 2019, prominent central bankers Stanley Fischer and Philip Hildebrand co-authored a paper published by BlackRock in which they propose a form of helicopter money.[153]

Carbon quantitative easing

Carbon quantitative easing (CQE) is an untested form of QE that is featured in a newly proposed international climate policy, called a global carbon reward.[154][155][156] A major goal of CQE is to finance the global carbon reward by managing the exchange rate of a new representative currency, called a carbon currency. The carbon currency will act as an international unit of account and a store of value, because it will represent the mass of carbon that is mitigated and rewarded under the global carbon reward policy.

Fiscal policy

Keynesian economics became popular after the Great Depression. The idea is that in an economy with low inflation and high unemployment (especially technological unemployment), demand side economics will stimulate consumer spending, which increases business profits, which increases investment. Keynesians promote methods like public works, infrastructure redevelopment, and increases in the social safety net to increase demand and inflation.

Monetary financing

Quantitative easing has been nicknamed "money printing" by some members of the media,[157][158][159] central bankers,[160] and financial analysts.[161][162]

However, QE is a very different form of money creation than it is commonly understood when talking about "money printing" (otherwise called monetary financing or debt monetization). Indeed, with QE the newly created money is usually used to buy financial assets beyond just government bonds[157] (corporate bonds etc.) and QE is usually implemented in the secondary market. In most developed nations (e.g., the United Kingdom, the United States, Japan, and the Eurozone), central banks are prohibited from buying government debt directly from the government and must instead buy it from the secondary market.[163][164] This two-step process, where the government sells bonds to private entities that in turn sell them to the central bank, has been called "monetizing the debt" by many analysts.[163]

The distinguishing characteristic between QE and debt monetization is that with the former, the central bank creates money to stimulate the economy, not to finance government spending (although an indirect effect of QE is to lower rates on sovereign bonds). Also, the central bank has the stated intention of reversing the QE when the economy has recovered (by selling the government bonds and other financial assets back into the market).[157] The only effective way to determine whether a central bank has monetized debt is to compare its performance relative to its stated objectives. Many central banks have adopted an inflation target. It is likely that a central bank is monetizing the debt if it continues to buy government debt when inflation is above target and if the government has problems with debt financing.[163]

Some economists such as Adair Turner have argued that outright monetary financing would be more effective than QE.[165][166]

Neo-Fisherism

Neo-Fisherism, based on theories made by Irving Fisher reasons that the solution to low inflation is not quantitative easing, but paradoxically to increase interest rates. This is due to the fact that if interest rates continue to decline, banks will lose customers and less money will be invested back into the economy.

In a situation of low inflation and high debt, customers will feel more secure holding on to cash or converting cash into commodities, which fails to stimulate economic growth. If the money supply increases from quantitative easing, customers will subsequently default in the face of higher prices, thus resetting the low inflation and worsening the low inflation issue.[167][168]

See also

References

  1. "Quantitative Easing". Bank of England.
  2. Michael Joyce, David Miles, Andrew Scott & Dimitri Vayanos, Quantitative Easing and Unconventional Monetary Policy – An Introduction, The Economic Journal, Vol. 122, No. 564 (November 2012), pp. F271-F288: "The most high-profile form of unconventional monetary policy has been Quantitative Easing (QE)."
  3. Oatley, Thomas (2019). International Political Economy: Sixth Edition. Routledge. pp. 369–370. ISBN 978-1-351-03464-7.
  4. McTeer, Bob (23 December 2010). "There's nothing wrong with the Fed printing money". Forbes.
  5. McTeer, Bob (26 August 2010). "Quantitative easing is a toxic phrase for a routine policy". Forbes.
  6. Joseph E. Gagnon, Quantitative Easing: An Underappreciated Success, Peterson Institute for International Economics, Policy Brief 16-4 (April 2016).
  7. Ricardo Reis, "Funding Quantitative Easing to Target Inflation", in "Designing Resilient Monetary Policy Frameworks for the Future”, Proceedings of the Jackson Hole Economic Policy Symposium: Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, August 2016, pp. 423–478.
  8. "A numbers game: How quantitative easing lifts stock prices". Banking Observer.
  9. McKenna, Barrie (27 April 2014). "An uneasy relationship behind response to financial crash". The Globe and Mail.
  10. "Quantitative easing: A therapy of last resort". The New York Times. 1 January 2009. Retrieved 12 July 2010.
  11. Stewart, Heather (29 January 2009). "Quantitative easing: last resort to get credit moving again". The Guardian. London. Retrieved 12 July 2010.
  12. Bullard, James (January 2010). "Quantitative Easing — Uncharted Waters for Monetary Policy". Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Retrieved 26 July 2011.
  13. "Q&A: Quantitative easing". BBC. 9 March 2009. Retrieved 29 March 2009.
  14. Lerven, Frank van (2016). "Quantitative Easing in the Eurozone: a One-Year Assessment". Intereconomics. 2016 (4): 237–242. doi:10.1007/s10272-016-0608-9. hdl:10419/191169. S2CID 189843544.
  15. "Quantitative easing, portfolio rebalancing and credit growth: micro evidence from Germany" (PDF).
  16. Luca Dedola, Georgios Georgiadis, Johannes Gräb, Arnaud Mehl (21 October 2020) "Quantitative easing policies and exchange rates". voxeu.org. Retrieved 18 December 2020.
  17. Bank of England chief attacks peers for calling quantitative easing an ‘addiction’. The Telegraph. 5 August 2021. Retrieved 17 August 2021.
  18. "The Financial Crisis, Then and Now: Ancient Rome and 2008 CE". Harvard University. 10 December 2018. Retrieved 31 May 2022.
  19. Hoover Institution, Economics Working Paper 14110, "Exiting from Low Interest Rates to Normality: An Historical Perspective", November 2014 Retrieved 10 March 2015.
  20. Pinto, Edward J. (27 April 2016). "The 30-year fixed mortgage should disappear". American Enterprise Institute.
  21. Stefan Homburg (2017) A Study in Monetary Macroeconomics, Oxford University Press, ISBN 978-0-19-880753-7.
  22. Telegraph, Federal Reserve ends QE, 29 October 2014 Retrieved 10 March 2015
  23. "Is QE2 finally the economic collapse?". Fortune (magazine). 11 August 2010.
  24. The Heritage Foundation, "Is the Inflation Threat Real? Is it Imminent?" Retrieved 10 March 2015
  25. "量的緩和". kotobank.jp.
  26. "Japan sets inflation goal in fight against deflation". BBC News. 16 February 2010. Retrieved 4 April 2011.
  27. Mark Spiegel. "FRBSF: Economic Letter—Quantitative Easing by the Bank of Japan (11/02/2001)". Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco. Retrieved 19 January 2009.
  28. Hiroshi Fujiki et al., "Monetary Policy under Zero Interest Rate: Viewpoints of Central Bank Economists Archived 21 January 2019 at the Wayback Machine", Monetary and Economic Studies, February 2001, p. 98. Retrieved 9 August 2010.
  29. Shirakawa, Masaaki, "One Year Under 'Quantitative Easing' Archived 21 January 2019 at the Wayback Machine", Institute for Monetary and Economic Studies, Bank of Japan, 2002.
  30. Bank of Japan, "New Procedures for Money Market Operations and Monetary Easing Archived 19 July 2009 at the Wayback Machine", 19 March 2001. Retrieved 9 August 2010.
  31. "Easing Out of the Bank of Japan's Monetary Easing Policy" (2004–33, 19 November 2004). Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco.
  32. "PIMCO/Tomoya Masanao interview". Archived from the original on 26 July 2010.
  33. Hiroshi Ugai (July 2006). "Effects of the Quantitative Easing Policy: A Survey of Empirical Analyses". Bank of Japan Working Paper.
  34. Alloway, Tracy, The Unthinkable Has Happened, ft.com, 10 November 2008. Retrieved 9 August 2010.
  35. 'Bernanke-san' Signals Policy Shift, Evoking Japan Comparison, Bloomberg.com, 2 December 2008
  36. Bank pumps £75bn into economy, ft.com, 5 March 2009
  37. "Federal Reserve announces it will initiate a program to purchase the direct obligations of housing-related government-sponsored enterprises and mortgage-backed securities backed by Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, and Ginnie Mae". Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
  38. Ali, Abdulmalik. "Quantitative Monetary Easing: The history and impacts on financial markets". academia.edu. Retrieved 14 February 2015.
  39. Censky, Annalyn (3 November 2010). "QE2: Fed pulls the trigger". CNNmoney.com. Retrieved 10 August 2011.
  40. "What is the Federal Reserve Quantitative Easing Archived 11 February 2015 at the Wayback Machine". useconomy.about.com (22 September 2011).
  41. Authers, John (5 November 2010). "Fed's desperate measure is a watershed moment". Financial Times.
  42. Conerly, Bill (13 September 2012). "QE3 and the Economy: It Will Help, But Not Solve All Problems". Forbes. Retrieved 13 September 2012.
  43. Inman, Phillip (14 July 2011). "Moody's sounds note of caution while Bernanke promises support for U.S. economy". The Guardian. London. Retrieved 19 July 2011.
  44. Zumbrun, Joshua (13 September 2012). "Fed Undertakes QE3 With $40 Billion MBS Purchases Per Month". Bloomberg News. Retrieved 13 September 2012.
  45. "Federal Reserve issues FOMC statement". Federal Reserve Board. 12 January 2012. Retrieved 1 January 2013.
  46. Jensen, Greg (19 September 2012). "QE3 Launched: The Ever Decreasing Effects of Monetary Stimulus". NASDAQ. Archived from the original on 20 September 2012. Retrieved 19 September 2012.
  47. Jason Haver (14 September 2012). "QE-Infinity: Poking Holes in Bernanke's Logic". Accessed 18 August 2018.
  48. "Federal Reserve issues FOMC statement" (Press release). Federal Reserve. 12 December 2012. Retrieved 18 August 2018.
  49. Dunstan Prial. "Bernanke Offers Possible Timetable for Tapering". Fox Business. Archived from the original on 22 June 2013. Retrieved 24 June 2013.
  50. Slatyer, Will (2015). The Life/Death Rhythms of Capitalist Regimes - Debt Before Dishonour: Timetable of World Dominance 1400-2100. Partridge Publishing Singapore. ISBN 9781482829617.
  51. "Fed Seen by Economists Tapering QE at September Meeting". Bloomberg.
  52. "Dow Jones down 4.3 percent since Fed chair Ben Bernanke took the podium". AL.com. 25 June 2013.
  53. "Analysis: Time to taper? Not if you look at bank loans". Reuters. 19 September 2013.
  54. JeeYeon Park (18 December 2013). "Fed to reduce bond purchases by $10 billion a month". Cnbc.com. Retrieved 13 September 2018.
  55. Appelbaum, Binyamin (29 October 2014). "Federal Reserve Caps Its Bond Purchases; Focus Turns to Interest Rates". The New York Times.
  56. Wolfers, Justin (29 October 2014). "The Fed Has Not Stopped Trying to Stimulate the Economy". The New York Times.
  57. "Federal Reserve Board - Recent balance sheet trends".
  58. "Federal Reserve cuts rates to zero and launches massive $700 billion quantitative easing program". CNBC. 15 March 2020.
  59. "Federal Reserve Board - Recent balance sheet trends". Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
  60. "The United Kingdom's quantitative easing policy: design, operation and impact" (PDF). Retrieved 30 June 2023.
  61. "Archived copy" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 31 December 2010. Retrieved 27 December 2010.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: archived copy as title (link)
  62. "Quantitative easing". www.bankofengland.co.uk.
  63. "A flat economy (cont'd)". BBC News. 12 January 2012.
  64. "Bank of England | Monetary Policy | Quantitative Easing Explained | Amount of Assets Purchased". www.bankofengland.co.uk. Archived from the original on 2 January 2011.
  65. Bean, Charles (July 2009). "Ask the Deputy Governor". Bank of England. Archived from the original on 26 July 2010. Retrieved 12 July 2010.
  66. Quantitative Easing explained (PDF). Bank of England. pp. 7–9. ISBN 1-85730-114-5. Archived from the original (PDF) on 30 October 2010. Retrieved 20 July 2010. (page 7) Bank buys assets from ... institutions ... credits the seller's bank account. So the seller has more money in their bank account, while their bank holds a corresponding claim against the Bank of England (known as reserves) ... (page 8) high-quality debt ... (page 9) ... such as shares or company bonds. That will push up the prices of those assets ...
  67. "The Distributional Effects of Asset Purchases". Bank of England. 12 July 2012. Retrieved 4 January 2020.
  68. "Exchange of letters between the Governor and the Chancellor on the Asset Purchase Facility - February 2022". 8 June 2023.
  69. "Exchange of letters between the Governor and the Chancellor on the Asset Purchase Facility - September 2022". 8 June 2023.
  70. "Gilt Market Operations - Market Notice 28 September 2022". 6 June 2023.
  71. "Pound hits record low after tax cut plans". BBC News. 26 September 2022.
  72. "Bank of England announces gilt market operation". 8 June 2023.
  73. Duncan, Gary (8 May 2009). "European Central Bank opts for quantitative easing to lift the eurozone". The Times. London.
  74. Jolly, David; Ewing, Jack (22 January 2015). "E.C.B. Stimulus Calls for 60 Billion Euros in Monthly Bond-Buying". The New York Times. ISSN 0362-4331. Retrieved 11 May 2022.
  75. "ECB: ECB announces expanded asset purchase programme". europa.eu. 22 January 2015.
  76. "ECB unveils massive QE boost for eurozone". BBC News. 22 January 2015.
  77. "Monetary policy decisions". European Central Bank. 12 September 2019. Retrieved 11 May 2022.
  78. Bank, European Central (18 March 2020). "ECB announces €750 billion Pandemic Emergency Purchase Programme (PEPP)". {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  79. "Our response to coronavirus (COVID-19)". European Central Bank. 19 February 2021.
  80. Blackstone, Brian; Wessel, David (8 January 2013). "Button-Down Central Bank Bets It All". The Wall Street Journal.
  81. Meier, Markus Diem. (16 December 2020) "Die USA verlangen von der Schweiz Erhöhung des Rentenalters" (in German). Tages Anzeiger. Retrieved 17 December 2020.
  82. Sweden cuts rates below zero and starts QE BBC News, Business, 12 February 2015
  83. "Quantitative Easing – A lesson learned from Japan". Oye Times.
  84. "Japan government and central bank intervene to cut yen". BBC News. 4 August 2011.
  85. Bank of Japan increases QE by 10 trillion yen Archived 6 October 2011 at the Wayback Machine. Banking Times (4 August 2011).
  86. "Bank of Japan increases stimulus and keeps rates low". BBC News. 27 October 2011.
  87. "'Price Stability Target' of 2 Percent and 'Quantitative and Qualitative Monetary Easing with Yield Curve Control'". Bank of Japan. Retrieved 18 August 2018.
  88. Stewart, Heather (4 April 2013). "Japan aims to jump-start economy with $1.4tn of quantitative easing". The Guardian. London.
  89. "Expansion of the Quantitative and Qualitative Monetary Easing" (PDF). Bank of Japan. 31 October 2014. Retrieved 18 August 2018.
  90. Charoenwong, Ben; Morck, Randall; Wiwattanakantang, Yupana (14 May 2021). "Bank of Japan Equity Purchases: The (Non-)Effects of Extreme Quantitative Easing*". Review of Finance. 25 (3): 713–743. doi:10.1093/rof/rfaa029. ISSN 1572-3097.
  91. Navarro, Bruno J. (12 July 2012). "CNBC Coverage of Greenspan". Finance.yahoo.com. Archived 18 July 2012 at the Wayback Machine
  92. "Speech by Governor Stein on evaluating large-scale asset purchases". Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 11 October 2012.
  93. Kempf, Elisabeth; Pastor, Lubos (5 October 2020). "Fifty shades of QE: Central bankers versus academics". VoxEU.org. Retrieved 30 March 2021.
  94. Gilchrist, Simon, and Egon Zakrajšek. "The Impact of the Federal Reserve's Large‐Scale Asset Purchase Programs on Corporate Credit Risk". Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 45.s2 (2013): 29–57.
  95. Gagnon, Joseph, et al. "Large-scale asset purchases by the Federal Reserve: did they work?" (2010).
  96. Cúrdia, Vasco, and Andrea Ferrero. "How stimulatory are large-scale asset purchases?" FRBSF Economic Letter 22 (2013): 1–5.
  97. Chen, Han, Vasco Cúrdia, and Andrea Ferrero. "The macroeconomic effects of large‐scale asset purchase programmes". The economic journal 122.564 (2012).
  98. Gagnon, Joseph, et al. "The financial market effects of the Federal Reserve's large-scale asset purchases". International Journal of Central Banking 7.1 (2011): 3–43.
  99. Irwin, Neil (31 October 2014). "Quantitative Easing is Ending. Here's What It Did, in Charts". The New York Times.
  100. Marcello., Siklos, Pierre L. Blot, Christophe. Creel, Jérôme. Hubert, Paul. Bonatti, Luigi. Fracasso, Andrea. Tamborini, Roberto. Beckmann, Joscha. Fiedler, Salomon. Gern, Klaus-Jürgen. Kooths, Stefan. Quast, Josefine. Wolters, Maik. Capolongo, Angela. Gros, Daniel. Benigno, Pierpaolo. Canofari, Paolo. Di Bartolomeo, Giovanni. Messori (2020). The ECB's asset purchase programmes : experience and future perspectives : compilation of papers. ISBN 978-92-846-7120-5. OCLC 1222784406.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  101. Blattner, Laura; Nogueira, Gil (2016). "The Effect of Quantitative Easing on Lending Conditions". SSRN Electronic Journal. doi:10.2139/ssrn.2749128. ISSN 1556-5068.
  102. The ECB's asset purchase programmes : effectiveness, risks, alternatives : monetary dialogue papers, September 2020. Joscha Beckmann, Salomon Fiedler, Klaus-Jürgen Gern, Stefan Kooths, Josefine Quast, Maik Wolters. [Brussels]. 2020. ISBN 978-92-846-7095-6. OCLC 1222783951.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link) CS1 maint: others (link)
  103. Gambetti, Luca; Musso, Alberto (June 2017). "The macroeconomic impact of the ECB's expanded asset purchase programme (APP)". Working Paper Series.
  104. Barbon, Andrea; Gianinazzi, Virginia (1 December 2019). "Quantitative Easing and Equity Prices: Evidence from the ETF Program of the Bank of Japan". The Review of Asset Pricing Studies. 9 (2): 210–255. doi:10.1093/rapstu/raz008. ISSN 2045-9920.
  105. Bowlby, Chris (5 March 2009). "The fear of printing too much money". BBC News. Retrieved 25 June 2011.
  106. Thornton, Daniel L. (2010). "The downside of quantitative easing" (PDF). Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Economic Synopses (34).
  107. John B. Taylor, The Fed's New View is a Little Less Scary, 20 June 2013 blog post
  108. John Taylor, Stanford, 2012 testimony before House Financial Service Committee, page two , retrieved 20 October 2013.
  109. Inman, Phillip (29 June 2011). "How the world paid the hidden cost of America's quantitative easing". The Guardian. London.
  110. M. Nicolas J. Firzli quoted in Sinead Cruise (4 August 2012). "Zero Return World Squeezes Retirement Plans". Reuters with CNBC. . Retrieved 5 August 2012.
  111. M. Nicolas J. Firzli (1 March 2013). "' Europe's Pension Predicament: the Broken Bismarckian Promise '". Plan Sponsor. . Archived from the original on 6 May 2013. Retrieved 1 March 2013.
  112. Henderson, Isaiah M. (4 May 2019). "On the Causes of European Political Instability". The California Review. Retrieved 19 July 2019.
  113. "ECB cash injections for polluters must stop, 70 NGOs demand |". corporateeurope.org. Corporate Europe Observatory. Retrieved 28 November 2020.
  114. "ECB's purchasing policies skewed towards carbon-intensive industries - report". Greenpeace European Unit. Retrieved 28 November 2020.
  115. admin. "The ECB's dirty quantitative easing". Reclaim Finance. Retrieved 28 November 2020.
  116. Dafermos, Yannis; Gabor, Daniela; Nikolaidi, Maria; Pawloff, Adam; Lerven, Frank van. "Decarbonising is easy". New Economics Foundation. Retrieved 28 November 2020.
  117. Jourdan, Kalinowski (4 April 2019). "REPORT: Aligning monetary policy with the EU's climate targets". Positive Money Europe. Retrieved 28 November 2020.
  118. "ECB policy is working, but new challenges need new responses | News | European Parliament". www.europarl.europa.eu. 2 December 2020. Retrieved 28 November 2020.
  119. Vasto, Alessia Del (11 February 2021). "EU Parliament pressures ECB to address climate change". Positive Money Europe. Retrieved 30 March 2021.
  120. "Climate change and central banks". www.bundesbank.de. Retrieved 28 November 2020.
  121. Colesanti Senni, Chiara; Monnin, Pierre (16 October 2020). "Central Bank Market Neutrality is a Myth". Council on Economic Policies. Retrieved 30 March 2021.
  122. Papoutsi, M., Piazzesi, M. and Schneider, M., (2021), “How unconventional is green monetary policy”, Working Paper.
  123. "ECB will consider dropping market neutrality – Lagarde". Central Banking. 15 October 2020. Retrieved 28 November 2020.
  124. "ECB market neutrality crumbling". OMFIF. 16 February 2021. Retrieved 30 March 2021.
  125. Schnabel, Isabel (28 September 2020). "When markets fail – the need for collective action in tackling climate change". {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  126. Reporter, Financial. "Bank of England considering attaching climate conditions to asset purchases". Financial Reporter. Retrieved 28 November 2020.
  127. "Adapting central bank operations to a hotter world: Reviewing some options". Banque de France. 24 March 2021. Retrieved 30 March 2021.
  128. "This is what Theresa May said about the kind of Prime Minister she'll be – and what she really meant". The Independent. 11 July 2016. Retrieved 13 September 2018.
  129. Frank, Robert (14 September 2012). "Does Quantitative Easing Mainly Help the Rich?". CNBC. Retrieved 21 May 2013.
  130. "Quarterly Bulletins" (PDF). Bank of England. 15 August 2018. Archived from the original (PDF) on 22 July 2017. Retrieved 13 September 2018.
  131. Elliott, Larry (23 August 2012). "Britain's richest 5% gained most from quantitative easing – Bank of England". The Guardian. London. Retrieved 21 May 2013.
  132. Belvedere, Matthew J. "QE Halt Would Be 'Too Violent' for Market: Fed's Fisher". CNBC. Retrieved 20 May 2013.
  133. "Transcript of Monetary Dialogue, 15 June 2015" (PDF). Retrieved 22 July 2016.
  134. "Monetary policy and household inequality" (PDF). ECB. July 2018.
  135. "Economists find ECB stimulus shrank eurozone inequality". France 24. 18 July 2018. Retrieved 27 September 2018.
  136. Jourdan, Stanislas; Fontan (10 May 2017). "How The ECB Boosts Inequality And What It Can Do About It". Social Europe. Retrieved 30 March 2021.
  137. Quantitative Easing and the Forex Market. Management Study Guide. Retrieved 18 December 2020.
  138. Rodrigo Fernandez & Pablo Bortz & Nicolas Zeolla, A critical assesment [sic] of the harmful impact of European monetary policy on developing countries SOMO, June 2018
  139. Jeff Black and Zoe Schneeweis, China's Yi Warns on Currency Wars as Yuan in Equilibrium, Bloomberg News, 26 January 2013
  140. John Paul Rathbone and Jonathan Wheatley, Brazil's finance chief attacks US over QE3, Financial Times, 20 September 2012
  141. Richard Blackden, Brazil president Dilma Rousseff blasts Western QE as monetary tsunami, The Daily Telegraph (London), 10 April 2012
  142. Michael Steen and Alice Ross, Warning on new currency war, Financial Times, 22 January 2013
  143. Blackden, Richard (29 March 2012). "BRICs attack QE and urge Western leaders to be 'responsible'". Daily Telegraph. ISSN 0307-1235. Archived from the original on 12 January 2022. Retrieved 7 October 2019.
  144. Lynch, David J. (17 November 2010). "Bernanke's 'Cheap Money' Stimulus Spurs Corporate Investment Outside U.S". Bloomberg.
  145. Eichengreen, Barry (11 June 2019). "Critics of quantitative easing should consider the alternative | Barry Eichengreen". The Guardian. ISSN 0261-3077. Retrieved 7 October 2019.
  146. Speeches by Richard W. Fisher. Dallas Fed (8 November 2010).
  147. Wolf, Martin. (16 December 2008) "'Helicopter Ben' confronts the challenge of a lifetime". Financial Times.
  148. Speech, Bernanke -Deflation- 21 November 2002. Federal Reserve Bank.
  149. "How about quantitative easing for the people?". Reuters. 1 August 2012. Archived from the original on 3 August 2012.
  150. "Print Less but Transfer More". Foreign Affairs. September–October 2014.
  151. "Combatting Eurozone deflation". VOX. 23 December 2014.
  152. "Better ways to boost eurozone economy and employment". Financial Times. 26 March 2015.
  153. Stanley Fischer, Elga Bartsch, Jean Boivin, Stanley Fischer, Philipp Hildebrand (August 2019). "Dealing with the next downturn: From unconventional monetary policy to unprecedented policy coordination" (PDF). BlackRock Institute.
  154. Chen, Delton B.; van der Beek, Joel; Cloud, Jonathan (3 July 2017). "Climate mitigation policy as a system solution: addressing the risk cost of carbon". Journal of Sustainable Finance & Investment. 7 (3): 233–274. doi:10.1080/20430795.2017.1314814. ISSN 2043-0795. S2CID 157277979.
  155. Chen, Delton B.; van der Beek, Joel; Cloud, Jonathan (2019), Doukas, Haris; Flamos, Alexandros; Lieu, Jenny (eds.), "Hypothesis for a Risk Cost of Carbon: Revising the Externalities and Ethics of Climate Change", Understanding Risks and Uncertainties in Energy and Climate Policy, Cham: Springer International Publishing, pp. 183–222, doi:10.1007/978-3-030-03152-7_8, ISBN 978-3-030-03151-0, S2CID 158251793, retrieved 25 August 2021
  156. Zappalà, Guglielmo (2018). "Central Banks' Role in Responding to Climate Change: Monetary Policy and Macroprudential Regulation". doi:10.13140/RG.2.2.33035.80167. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  157. Stephanomics: Is quantitative easing really just printing money?. BBC.
  158. Mackintosh, James. (2 December 2010) QE: Replacement not debasement. FT.com.
  159. Hyde, Deborah. (8 November 2010) Ask Citywire: Quantitative easing part II – Citywire Money. Citywire.co.uk.
  160. Bullard, James (30 June 2009). Exit Strategies for the Federal Reserve (PDF) (Speech). Global Interdependence Center, Philadelphia, Pennsylvania, United States. Retrieved 26 June 2011.
  161. "Bank of England to create new money: a Q&A". The Daily Telegraph. London. 5 March 2009. Archived from the original on 13 September 2012.
  162. Duncan, Gary (5 March 2009). "Bank should start printing money says Times MPC". The Times. London.
  163. http://research.stlouisfed.org/publications/es/10/ES1014.pdf Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
  164. Stephanomics. BBC.
  165. Reichlin, Lucrezia; Turner, Adair; Woodford, Michael (23 September 2019). "Helicopter money as a policy option". VoxEU.org. Retrieved 30 March 2021.
  166. Adair Turner (2015). "The Case for Monetary Finance – An Essentially Political Issue" (Conference paper). IMF. Retrieved 30 June 2023.
  167. "Neo-Fisherism: A Radical Idea, or the Most Obvious Solution to the Low-Inflation Problem?". 20 July 2016.
  168. https://www.stlouisfed.org/publications/regional-economist/july-2016/neo-fisherism-a-radical-idea-or-the-most-obvious-solution-to-the-low-inflation-problem Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
This article is issued from Wikipedia. The text is licensed under Creative Commons - Attribution - Sharealike. Additional terms may apply for the media files.