Rent control in the United States
In the United States, rent control refers to laws or ordinances that set price controls on the rent of residential housing to function as a price ceiling.[1] More loosely, "rent control" describes several types of price control:
- "strict price ceilings", also known as "rent freeze" systems, or "absolute" or "first generation" rent controls, in which no increases in rent are allowed at all (rent is typically frozen at the rate existing when the law was enacted);
- "vacancy control", also known as "strict" or "strong" rent control, in which the rental price can rise but continues to be regulated in between tenancies (a new tenant pays almost the same rent as the previous tenant); and
- "vacancy decontrol", also known as "tenancy" or "second-generation" rent control, which limits price increases during a tenancy but allows rents to rise to market rate between tenancies (new tenants pay market rate rent but increases are limited as long as they remain).[1]
Part of a series on |
Living spaces |
---|
As of 2022, seven states (California, New York, New Jersey, Maryland, Maine, Oregon, and Minnesota) and the District of Columbia have localities in which some form of residential rent control is in effect (for normal structures, excluding mobile homes).[2] Thirty-seven states either prohibit or preempt rent control, while seven states allow their cities to enact rent control but have no cities that have implemented it.[3][4] For localities with rent control, it often covers a large percentage of that city's stock of rental units. For example, in New York City as of 2017, 45% of rental units were "rent stabilized" and 1% were "rent controlled" (these are different legal classifications in NYC).[5] In the District of Columbia as of 2019, about 36% of rental units were rent controlled.[6] In San Francisco as of 2014, about 75% of all rental units were rent controlled,[7]: 1 and in Los Angeles in 2014, 80% of multifamily units were rent controlled.[8]: 1
In 2019, Oregon's legislature passed a bill which made the state the first in the nation to adopt a state-wide rent control policy. This new law limits annual rent increases to inflation plus 7 percent, includes vacancy decontrol (market rate between tenancies), exempts new construction for 15 years, and keeps the current state ban on local rent control policies (state level preemption) intact.[9]: 1 [10]: 1 In November 2021, voters in Saint Paul, Minnesota, passed a rent control ballot initiative that capped annual rent increases at 3 percent, included vacancy control, and did not exempt new construction or allow inflation to be added to the allowable rate increase.[11][12] This resulted in an 80% reduction in requests for new multifamily housing permits, while in neighboring Minneapolis, where voters authorized the city council to craft a rent control ordinance which might exempt new construction, permits were up 70%.[11][13]
There is a consensus among economists that rent control reduces the quality and quantity of rental housing units.[14][15][16][17][18][19][20] Other observers see rent control as benefiting the renter, preventing excessive rent increases and unfair evictions. Rent control may stabilize a community, promoting continuity, and it may mitigate income inequality.[21][22][23]
History
In the United States during World War I, rents were "controlled" through a combination of public pressure and the efforts of local anti-rent-profiteering committees. Between 1919 and 1924, a number of cities and states adopted rent- and eviction-control laws. Modern rent controls were first adopted in response to the Great Depression and WWII- era shortages. Because of these shortages and the overall national economic crisis, the federal government called for emergency price control on consumer goods and rent control in 1942.[24] However, not all states decided to implement these rent control laws.
It was not until the 1970s, during the economic recession, that Richard Nixon temporarily implemented a national wage and price controls to combat hyperinflation, but this did not last for long and began to phase out in 1973. Nonetheless, tenants particularly in Berkeley kept organizing and brought rent stabilization to the June 6, 1973 L972 ballot. They won and Berkeley became the first city in California to have rent control since World War II.[24] Other cities around the country followed and some still remain in effect or have been reintroduced in certain cities with large tenant populations, such as New York City, San Francisco, Los Angeles, Washington, D.C., and Oakland, California. Many smaller communities also have rent control — notably the California cities of Santa Monica, Berkeley, and West Hollywood[25] — along with many small towns in New Jersey. In the early 1990s, rent control in some cities, such as Boston and Cambridge, Massachusetts, was ended by state referendums.[26] When rent control ended in Cambridge, the city realized a 20% increase in new development and an increase in property values, according to a study by the MIT Center for Real Estate.[27]
History reveals that these regulations are constantly in flux and adapting to situations such as natural disasters, economic crises, and pandemics. These changes do not always look the same and vary within each state and city. For example, due to COVID-19, Oakland, California implemented a moratorium to prevent evictions from happening, which ended in February 2021.[28] Whereas in Massachusetts the eviction moratorium ended on October 17, 2020, and there was a CDC moratorium that stopped physical removals in cases where tenants owed rent due to illness or job loss until December 31, 2020.[29]
New York
New York State has had the longest history of rent controls, since 1943. New York City contains the majority of units covered by rent control. Rent control laws have stayed on the books for decades in New York because of an inadequate supply of "decent, affordable housing".[30] The worsening in the rental market led to the enactment of the Rent Stabilization Law of 1969, which aimed to help increase the number of available rental units. The current system is very complicated, and most of the protected renters are elderly.[31] William A. Moses, the founder of the Community Housing Improvement Program, a trade association that represents the owners of over 4,000 apartment buildings in New York City, said in 1983 that rent control was "the principal reason for neighborhood deterioration" and that at least 300,000 apartment units would have been built in New York City without it. Moses argued that landlords might not maintain their property if they were not allowed to collect adequate rent.[32] Urban planning scholar Peter Marcuse said in 1983 that rent control was not the reason for some landlords abandoning their NYC properties at the low end of the market – instead, such abandonment stemmed from the inability of low-income renters to pay the maximum rent allowed by law.[32] New York expanded rent control to encompass other municipalities in 2019 through the passage of the Housing Stability and Tenant Protection Act of 2019.[33] Since then, opponents have argued these new rent control regulations hinder investment in multifamily properties in New York City.[34] New York's rent control laws have also received criticism for inadvertently benefiting affluent tenants who might not otherwise need rental assistance.[35] Additionally, a survey of property owners who own or manage rent stabilized units in New York City found that rent regulations would lead to fewer non-essential improvements and proactive maintenance at their buildings.[36]
California
In California, municipal enactment of rent controls followed the high inflation of the 1970s (causing rents to continually rise)[37]: 1 and the 1979 statewide Proposition 13, which set property tax rates at 1%, and capped yearly increases at 2%. Leading the campaign to enact Proposition 13, California politician Howard Jarvis tried to get tenants to vote for Prop 13 by claiming that landlords would pass tax savings along to tenants; when most failed to do so, it became an additional motivating factor for rent control.[37]: 2
In 1985, California adopted the Ellis Act, eliminating municipalities' ability to prohibit the removal of properties from rental activities after the California Supreme Court in Nash v. City of Santa Monica[38] ruled that municipalities could prevent landlords from "going out of business" and withdrawing their properties from the rental market.New Study Calls for Ellis Act Reform
"Strong" or "vacancy control" rent control laws were in effect in five California cities (West Hollywood, Santa Monica, Berkeley, East Palo Alto, and Cotati) in 1995, when AB 1164 (known as the Costa-Hawkins Rental Housing Act) preempted some elements of municipal rent control ordinances and eliminated strong rent-control in California (except in special cases like mobile home parks).[39][40][41]
In 2018, a statewide initiative (Proposition 10) attempted to repeal the Costa-Hawkins law, which, if passed, would have allowed cities and municipalities to enact "strong" or "vacancy control" systems, allowed rent control to be applied to buildings built after 1995, and would have allowed rent control on single-family homes. All are currently prohibited by Costa-Hawkins.[42]: 1 The proposition failed 59% to 41%.[43][44]
In 2019, the California legislature passed and the governor signed AB 1482, which created a statewide rent cap for the next 10 years.[45] The Tenant Protection Act of 2019 caps annual rent increases at 5% plus regional inflation.[45] For example, had the bill been in effect in 2019, rent increases in Los Angeles would have been capped at 8.3%, and in San Francisco at 9%.[45] The increases are pegged to the rental rate as of March 15, 2019.[45] The new law does not apply to buildings built within the prior 15 years, or to single-family homes (unless owned by corporations or institutional investors).[45] It also includes a requirement to show "just cause" for evictions, and retains "vacancy decontrol", meaning that rents can increase to market rate between tenants.[45]
In 2020, Michael Weinstein, the founder of the AIDS Healthcare Foundation, sponsored and financed a second ballot initiative to allow more rent control, because he felt that AB 1482 (above) did not provide enough tenant protections, such as limiting rent increases between tenants.[45] 2020 California Proposition 21, like its predecessor 2018 California Proposition 10, was funded almost exclusively by Weinstein's AIDS Healthcare Foundation, and failed by an almost identical margin.[45][46][47]
Massachusetts
Rent control existed in Massachusetts between 1970 and 1994 when it was repealed by ballot initiative. During its existance, those who lived in rent controlled apartments included Ruth Abrams, a Justice of the Massachusetts Supreme Judicial Court, and Frederik, Crown Prince of Denmark.[48] It was blamed for the death of at least one landlord, due to the stress caused by a ruling from a rent control board that would require him to raise his entire house to create a new, legal apartment in the basement.[49][50][51]
Mobile homes
In some regions, rent control laws are more commonly adopted for mobile home parks.[52] Reasons given for these laws include residents owning their homes while renting the land the home sits on, the high cost of moving mobile homes, and the loss of home value when they are moved. California, for example, has only 13 local apartment rent control laws but over 100 local mobile home rent control laws. No new mobile home parks have been built in California since 1991.
Law
Rent control laws define which rental units are affected, and may only cover larger complexes, or units older than a certain date. To attempt to not disincentivise investment in new housing stock, rent control laws often exempt new construction. For example, San Francisco's Rent Stabilization Ordinance exempts all units built after 1979.[53] New York State generally exempts units built after 1974 anywhere in the state (although owners can agree to rent stabilization in exchange for tax benefits).[54]
The frequency and degree of rent increases are limited, usually to the rate of inflation defined by the United States Consumer Price Index or to a fraction thereof. San Francisco, for example, allows annual rent increases of 60% of the CPI, up to a maximum 7%.[55]
Rent control laws are often administered by nonelected rent control boards. Officers in city government assign members of the board, which will ensure mixed numbers of tenants and property owners to balance out their benefits. As stated in Goodman's research, a typical rent control board in New York is structured by two tenants, two landlords, and one homeowner. (Gilderbloom & Markham, 1996).[56]
Federal law
Rent regulation in the United States is an issue for each state. In 1921, the Supreme Court of the United States case of Block v. Hirsh[57] held by a majority that regulation of rents in the District of Columbia as a temporary emergency measure was constitutional, but shortly afterwards in 1924 in Chastleton Corp v. Sinclair[58] the same law was unanimously struck down by the Supreme Court. After the 1930s New Deal, the Supreme Court ceased to interfere with social and economic legislation, and a growing number of states adopted rules. In the 1986 case of Fisher v. City of Berkeley,[59] the US Supreme court held that there was no incompatibility between rent control and the Sherman Act.
State and local law
Oregon and California are the only states with statewide rent control laws, both enacted in 2019.[60][45] Six states—California, New York, New Jersey, Maine, Maryland, and Minnesota—have localities in which some form of residential rent control is in effect.[61][62] The District of Columbia also has rent control for some rental units; publicly owned or assisted properties, properties built in 1978 or later, and properties held by an owner with fewer than five rental units are exempt from D.C.'s rent-control law.[63]
Thirty-seven states either prohibit or preempt rent control, while eight states allow their cities to enact rent control, but have no cities that have implemented it.[3][4]
As of 2019, about 182 U.S. municipalities have rent control: 99 in New Jersey, 63 in New York, 18 in California, one in Maryland, and Washington, D.C.[61] The five most populous cities with rent control are New York City; Los Angeles; San Francisco; Oakland; and Washington, D.C.[61] The sole Maryland municipality with rent control is Takoma Park.[64]
Impact
There is a consensus among economists that rent control reduces the quality and quantity of housing.[65][66]: 106 [67]: 204 [68]: 1 A 2009 review of the economic literature[66]: 106 by Blair Jenkins found that "the economics profession has reached a rare consensus: Rent control creates many more problems than it solves".[66]: 105 [69]: 1 [70]: 1 [71]: 1 In a 2013 analysis of the body of economic research on rent control by Peter Tatian at the Urban Institute (a think tank described both as "liberal"[72] and "independent"[73][74]), he stated that "The conclusion seems to be that rent stabilization doesn't do a good job of protecting its intended beneficiaries—poor or vulnerable renters—because the targeting of the benefits is very haphazard.", and concluded that: "Given the current research, there seems to be little one can say in favor of rent control." [69]: 1 [75]: 1 [76]: 1 Two economists from opposing sides of the political spectrum, Nobel Laureate Paul Krugman (who identifies as an American liberal or European social democrat),[77] and Thomas Sowell, (who stated that "libertarian" might best describe his views)[78]: 1 have both criticized rent regulation as poor economics, which, despite its good intentions, leads to the creation of less housing, raises prices, and increases urban blight.[68]: 1 [79]: 4 [78]: 1 Writing in 1946, economists Milton Friedman and George J. Stigler said: "Rent ceilings, therefore, cause haphazard and arbitrary allocation of space, inefficient use of space, retardation of new construction and indefinite continuance of rent ceilings, or subsidization of new construction and a future depression in residential building."[80]
Historically, there have been two types of rent control – vacancy control (where the rent level of a unit is controlled irrespective of whether the tenant remains in the unit or not) and vacancy decontrol (where the rent level is controlled only while the existing tenant remains in the unit). In California prior to 1997, both types were allowed (the Costa/Hawkins bill of that year phased out vacancy control provisions). A 1990 study of Santa Monica, CA showed that vacancy control in that city protected existing tenants (lower increases in rent and longer stability). However, the policy potentially discouraged investors from building new rental units.[81]
A 2000 study that compared the border areas of four California cities having vacancy control provisions (Santa Monica, Berkeley, West Hollywood, East Palo Alto) with the border areas of adjoining jurisdictions (two of which allowed vacancy decontrol, including Los Angeles, and two of which had no rent control) showed that existing tenants in the vacancy control cities had lower rents and longer tenure than in the comparison areas. Thus, the ordinances helped protect the existing tenants and, therefore, increased community stability. However, there were fewer new rental units created in the border areas of the vacancy controlled cities over the 10-year period.[82]
A study that compared the effects of local rent control measures (both vacancy control and vacancy decontrol) with other local growth management measures in 490 California cities and counties (including all the largest ones) showed that rent control was stronger than individual land use restrictions (but not the aggregate effect of all growth restrictions) in reducing the number of rental units constructed between 1980 and 1990.[83] The measures (both rent control and growth management) helped displace new construction from the metropolitan areas to the interiors of the state with low income and minority populations being particularly impacted.
In 1994, San Francisco voters passed a ballot initiative which expanded the city's existing rent control laws to include small multi-unit apartments with four or less units, built prior to 1980 (about 30% of the city's rental housing stock at the time). [84]: 7 [85]: 1 [86]: 1 In 2017, Stanford economics researcher Rebecca Diamond and others published a study which examined the effects of this specific rent control law on the rental units newly controlled compared to similar style units (multi-unit apartments with four or less units) not under rent control (built after 1980), as well as this law's effect on the total city rental stock, and on overall rent prices in the city, covering the years from 1995 to 2012. [85][86][87] [88]: 1 [89]: 1 [90] They found that while San Francisco's rent control laws benefited tenants who had rent controlled units, it also resulted in landlords removing 30% of the units in the study from the rental market, (by conversion to condos or TICs) which led to a 15% citywide decrease in total rental units, and a 7% increase in citywide rents. [84]: 1,44 [85] [86]: 1 [87][88] The authors stated that "This substitution toward owner occupied and high-end new construction rental housing likely fueled the gentrification of San Francisco, as these types of properties cater to higher income individuals." [84]: 3 [85] [86]: 1 [87][88] [89]: 1 The authors also noted that "...forcing landlords to provide insurance against rent increases leads to large losses to tenants. If society desires to provide social insurance against rent increases, it would be more desirable to offer this subsidy in the form of a government subsidy or tax credit. This would remove landlords' incentives to decrease the housing supply and could provide households with the insurance they desire." [84]: 44 [85]: 1 [86]: 1 [87]: 1 [88]: 1 [89]: 1 [90]: 1
The rental-accommodation market suffers from information asymmetries and high transaction costs. Typically, a landlord has more information about a home than a prospective tenant can reasonably detect. Moreover, once the tenant has moved in, the costs of moving again are very high. Unscrupulous landlords could conceal defects and, if the tenant complains, threaten to raise the rent at the end of the lease. With rent control, tenants can request that hidden defects, if they exist, be repaired to comply with building code requirements, without fearing retaliatory rent increases. Rent control could thus compensate somewhat for inefficiencies of the housing market.[1]: 1 [91] In older buildings, rent control may broaden incentives to renovate individual units: tenants may invest sweat equity and their own money to improve their homes if they are protected from landlords trying to capture the added value,[92][93] while vacancy decontrol preserves landlords' financial incentive to renovate vacant units because it allows them to re-rent at market value.
According to a 2018 review of new research by Rebecca Diamond, new research showed that rent control benefitted tenants in the short-run, but had adverse effects for tenants and neighborhood stability in the long-run by reducing affordability, increasing gentrification, and creating negative spillovers for nearby neighborhoods.[94] Landlords frequently responded to rent control policies by reconverting rentals into buildings exempt from rent control or by allowing rentals to decay.[94]
A 2019 NBER working paper, which evaluated the efficacy of different housing affordability government policies, found that better targeting of rent control (towards the neediest households) could be welfare improving.[95] A 2021 study modelled rent control policies and found that they may raise housing prices and reduce housing quantities, but that "well-designed rent control may help policymakers to stabilize housing market dynamics, even without creating housing market distortions".[96]
Commentary
In 2000, New York Times columnist and Princeton University economist Paul Krugman published a frequently cited column on rent control.[97] He wrote, "The analysis of rent control is among the best-understood issues in all of economics, and – among economists anyway – one of the least controversial. In 1992, a poll of the American Economic Association found 93 percent of its members agreeing that 'a ceiling on rents reduces the quality and quantity of housing."
In light of recent legislative activity and ballot initiatives, several editorial boards have weighed in on rent control. In March 2019, the Chicago Tribune noted,[98] "The cost of rent control would be borne throughout the city in ways that, over time, would leave Chicago worse off. Even for many renters." In September 2019, the Washington Post argued,[99] "Rent-controlled laws can be good for some privileged beneficiaries, who are often not the people who really need help. But they are bad for many others." In September 2019, the Wall Street Journal wrote,[100] "Economists of all stripes agree rent control doesn't work. A mere 2% think it has positive effects, according to a 2012 survey by the IGM Forum."
Tenants' rights activists argue that rent control is necessary in times of long term housing shortages (See California housing shortage) to reduce the human suffering caused by increasing rents and the homelessness which results when people who can no longer afford the rent increases get evicted.[101]: 1 Milton Friedman argued that rent control restricts the property rights of property owners,[80] as it limits what they may do with their property, requiring petitioning and other processes by law, prior to taking action against a renter.
See also
- Affordable housing
- Price ceiling
- Subsidized housing
- Rent control in New York
- Rent control in California
- Rent regulation
People
- Don A. Allen, member of the California State Assembly and of the Los Angeles City Council in the 1940s and 1950s, urged lifting of wartime rent controls in Los Angeles
Notes
- Cruz, Christian (2009-01-19). "The pros and cons of rent control". Global Property Guide. Archived from the original on 2010-02-27. Retrieved 2018-08-05.
- "Rent Control Laws by State". www.nmhc.org. Retrieved 2023-03-17.
- "Rent Control Laws by State". National Multifamily Housing Council. 20 September 2019. Archived (PDF) from the original on 2018-08-03. Retrieved 2020-02-10.
- "US Rent Control Laws by State". rentprep.com. Archived from the original on 2019-09-18. Retrieved 2019-09-18.
- Waickman, C. R., Jerome, J. B. R., Place, R. Sociodemographics of Rent Stabilized Tenants. New York City Department of Housing Preservation and Development, 2018.
- "Roughly 36 percent of D.C.'s rental housing units are rent-stabilized". D.C. Policy Center. 4 December 2019. Retrieved 2022-09-14.
- Cutler, Kim-Mai (2014-04-14). "How Burrowing Owls Lead To Vomiting Anarchists (Or SF's Housing Crisis Explained)". TechCrunch. Archived from the original on 2014-04-30. Retrieved 2018-12-04.
- Bergman, Ben (2014-09-12). "LA Rent: Has rent control been successful in Los Angeles?". Southern California Public Radio. Archived from the original on 2014-09-13. Retrieved 2018-12-04.
- Ingber, Sasha (February 27, 2019). "Oregon Set To Pass The First Statewide Rent Control Bill". NPR.org. Archived from the original on 2019-03-06. Retrieved 2019-03-06.
- Njus, Elliot (February 28, 2019). "Oregon Gov. Kate Brown signs nation's first statewide rent control law". OregonLive. Archived from the original on 2019-03-05. Retrieved 2019-03-06.
- Britschgi, Christian (2022-03-22). "America's Most Controversial Rent Control Law Is Getting a Hasty Makeover - A collapse in new development activity followed St. Paul voters' approval of a strict, vaguely written rent control ordinance. City and state officials are scrambling over how best to fix the new law". Reason.
Tomorrow the St. Paul City Council will discuss the details of implementing Question 1, a brief, voter-passed ordinance that caps annual rent increases at 3 percent and which includes none of the typical exemptions or allowances for new construction, vacant units, or inflation. ... California and Oregon policies also include a number of other exemptions to their state-level rent control laws. They allow property owners, up to a point, to add inflation to allowable rent increases. They both allow landlords to raise rents as high as they want between tenants and have higher caps on rent increases: 5 percent in California and 7 percent in Oregon.
- Galioto, Katie (2021-11-20). "Fearing a spike, tenant advocates keep a close eye on St. Paul rents". Star Tribune.
More than 30,000 St. Paul residents — about 53% of voters — approved an ordinance by referendum earlier this month that will cap annual rent increases at 3%. The city has yet to hammer out the finer points of its new policy, which has been pegged as one of the most stringent rent control measures in the nation because it does not allow landlords to raise rents once a tenant moves out, does not exempt new construction and is not tied to inflation.
- Callaghan, Peter (2022-03-16). "Minnesota Senate committee moves bill to retroactively cancel rent control measures passed by voters in Minneapolis, St. Paul". MinnPost.
Draheim also cited Census Bureau statistics that show requests for housing permits has fallen 80 percent in St. Paul since the passage of the referendum. In Minneapolis, which hasn't drafted an ordinance yet and where new buildings could be exempt from caps, permits are up 68 percent.
- Baumol, William J; Blinder, Alan S. (1994). Economics Principles and Policy (6th ed.). Dryden Press. pp. 92–93, 379. ISBN 0-03-098927-2.
- Cooter, Robert; Ulen, Thomas (1997). Law and Economics 2nd Edition. Addison-Wesley. pp. 32–33.
- David A Besanko; Ronald R. Braeutigam (2008). "10.5". Microeconomics (3rd ed.). Hoboken, New Jersey: John Wiley & Sons. pp. 374–377. ISBN 978-0470-04924-2.
- B. Douglas Bernheim; Michael D Whinston (2008). Microeconomics (1st ed.). McGraw-Hill Irwin. p. 565. ISBN 978-0-07-290027-9.
- Dougherty, Conor (12 October 2018). "Why Rent Control Is a Lightning Rod". The New York Times. Retrieved 26 March 2019.
And yet economists from both the right and the left are in almost universal agreement that rent control makes housing problems worse in the long run.
- Mankiw, N. Gregory (2015). Principles of Economics. Boston, MA: Cengage Learning. p. 31. ISBN 978-1-305-58512-6.
- Brandts, Jordi; Busom, Isabel; Lopez-Mayan, Cristina; Panadés, Judith (2022). "Pictures are worth many words: Effectiveness of visual communication in dispelling the rent-control misconception". SSRN Electronic Journal. doi:10.2139/ssrn.4037381. hdl:2445/183641. ISSN 1556-5068. S2CID 247724304.
- Barton, Stephen (April 15, 2018). "Stephen Barton: Why rent control is a good thing". Santa Cruz Sentinel. Retrieved August 17, 2022.
- Barton, Stephen (July 3, 2018). "Steady rise in Bay Area rents fuels debate over November measure". San Jose Mercury News. Retrieved August 17, 2022.
- Walker, Richard (March 2016). "Why Is There a Housing Crisis?". East Bay Express. Retrieved August 17, 2022.
- "History of the Rent Control Debate in California". No Place Like Home. Archived from the original on 2020-09-26. Retrieved 2020-11-28.
- California, Department of Consumer Affairs, State of. "Landlord/Tenant Book - California Department of Consumer Affairs". www.dca.ca.gov. Archived from the original on 2017-10-10. Retrieved 2008-02-06.
{{cite web}}
: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link) - Massachusetts Election Statistics 1994: Ballot Question #9. [Boston?] : The Division. 1994.
- Pollakowski, Henry (May 2003). "Rent Control and Housing Investment: Evidence from Deregulation in Cambridge, Massachusetts" (PDF). MIT Center for Real Estate. Archived (PDF) from the original on October 21, 2019. Retrieved October 21, 2019.
- "Municode Library". library.municode.com. Archived from the original on 2021-03-09. Retrieved 2020-12-09.
- "Temporary Halt in Residential Evictions To Prevent the Further Spread of COVID-19". Federal Register. 2020-09-04. Archived from the original on 2020-12-09. Retrieved 2020-12-09.
- "History of Rent Regulation". www.tenant.net. Archived from the original on 2004-05-06. Retrieved 2004-04-15.
- "Rent Control Fact Sheet". Archived from the original on 2005-05-09.
- Plakins, Ava (January 31, 1983). "The Landlord's Lament". New York. Archived from the original on March 9, 2021. Retrieved February 25, 2019.
- "NY State Senate Bill S6458". NY State Senate. 2019-06-11. Archived from the original on 2019-07-20. Retrieved 2019-10-21.
- Board, The Editorial (19 July 2019). "Opinion | The Wages of Rent Control". Wall Street Journal. Archived from the original on 2019-10-21. Retrieved 2019-10-21.
- Louis, Errol (15 August 2019). "Rent laws are welfare for the rich: Time for New York to have a smart conversation over a costly housing regulatory system". nydailynews.com. Archived from the original on 2019-11-11. Retrieved 2019-10-21.
- REW (2019-08-28). "Owners cut spending, lay off workers as state rent regs begin to bite". Real Estate Weekly. Archived from the original on 2019-10-21. Retrieved 2019-10-21.
- Forbes, Jim; Sheridan, Matthew (1999-06-01). "The Birth of Rent Control in San Francisco". San Francisco Apartment Association. Archived from the original on 2008-07-20. Retrieved 2018-08-05.
- "Nash v. City of Santa Monica (1984)". Justia. 1984-10-25. Archived from the original on 2015-12-02. Retrieved 2018-08-05.
- "AB1164 Bill Text". Archived from the original on 2014-12-18. Retrieved 2007-12-01.
- "California Civil Code Sections 1954.50-1954.535". Archived from the original on 2012-02-11. Retrieved 2007-12-01.
- Peter Dreier (May 14, 1997). "Rent Deregulation in California and Massachusetts: Politics, Policy, and Impacts – Part II". Archived from the original on October 22, 2007. Retrieved October 18, 2007.
- Murphy, Katy (2018-11-06). "California's rent-control measure defeated". San Jose Mercury News. Archived from the original on 2018-11-17. Retrieved 2018-11-25.
- "State Ballot Measures" (PDF). Secretary of State of California. Archived (PDF) from the original on 2019-01-08. Retrieved 2019-03-03.
State Totals 4,949,543 7,251,443 Percent 40.6% 59.4%
- "California Proposition 10, Local Rent Control Initiative (2018)". Archived from the original on 2019-02-25. Retrieved 2019-03-04.
- Dillon, Liam (2019-10-08). "California will limit rent increases under bill signed by Gov. Gavin Newsom". Los Angeles Times.
- "California Proposition 10, Local Rent Control Initiative (2018)". Ballotpedia. Retrieved 2020-07-31.
- "California Proposition 21, Local Rent Control Initiative (2020)". Ballotpedia. Retrieved 2020-07-31.
- "'THE WEEK'". Vol. 46, no. 20. National Review. October 24, 1994. p. 10-24.
- Jacoby, Jeff. "At stake in Question 9: fairness for property owners". The Boston Globe. p. 15.
- Lewis, Diane (January 5, 1990). "Cambridge settles rent control case". The Boston Globe. p. 36.
- Chong, Curtis R. (November 7, 1994). "Citizens Dispute Question 9". The Harvard Crimson. Retrieved October 22, 2023.
- Hirsch, Werner Z. (1988-09-01). "An inquiry into effects of mobile home park rent control". Journal of Urban Economics. 24 (2): 212–226. doi:10.1016/0094-1190(88)90039-3. ISSN 0094-1190. Archived from the original on 2021-03-09. Retrieved 2021-02-26.
- "San Francisco Rent Board: Fact Sheet 1 – General Information".
- "Fact Sheet #1 - Rent Control and Rent Stabilization". Archived from the original on 2008-02-15. Retrieved 2008-01-17.
- "CITY AND COUNTY OF SAN FRANCISCO RESIDENTIAL RENT STABILIZATION AND ARBITRATION BOARD Section 1.12". Retrieved 2015-03-29.
- Gilderbloom, John I.; Markham, John P. (2016). "Moderate Rent Control: Sixty Cities over 20 Years". Journal of Urban Affairs. 18 (4): 409–430. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9906.1996.tb00388.x.
- 256 U.S. 135 (1921)
- 264 U.S. 543 (1924)
- 475 U.S. 260 (1986)
- Elliot Njus, How does Oregon's first-in-the-nation rent control law work? A quick guide Archived 2020-12-11 at the Wayback Machine, The Oregonian/OregonLive (March 6, 2019).
- Prasanna Rajasekaran, Mark Treskon, and Solomon Greene, Rent Control: What Does the Research Tell Us about the Effectiveness of Local Action? Archived 2021-01-22 at the Wayback Machine, Urban Institute (January 2019).
- "Rent Control Laws by State". www.nmhc.org. Retrieved 2022-07-15.
- Peter A. Tatian & Ashley Williams, A Rent Control Report for the District of Columbia Prepared by NeighborhoodInfo DC Archived 2021-01-01 at the Wayback Machine, Urban Institute (June 2011).
- Armando Trull, Rents At Takoma Park Building Help Spur Debate Over Maryland Tenant Protections Archived 2021-03-09 at the Wayback Machine, WAMU (September 17, 2015).
- "Rent control". www.igmchicago.org. Archived from the original on 2020-08-08. Retrieved 2019-10-21.
- Jenkins, Blair (1 January 2009). "Rent Control: Do Economists Agree?" (PDF). American Institute for Economic Research. Archived (PDF) from the original on 2017-09-29. Retrieved 2018-08-14.
- Alston, Richard M.; Kearl, J. R.; Vaughan, Michael B. (1992-05-01). "Is There a Consensus Among Economists in the 1990s?" (PDF). The American Economic Review. 82 (2): 203–209. JSTOR 2117401. Archived (PDF) from the original on 2006-09-01.
- Krugman, Paul (7 June 2000). "Reckonings; A Rent Affair". The New York Times. Archived from the original on 2009-04-06. Retrieved 2018-08-10.
- Tatian, Peter (2013-01-02). "Is Rent Control Good Policy?". Urban Institute. Archived from the original on 2015-07-03. Retrieved 2018-08-19.
- Beyer, Scott (2015-04-24). "How Ironic: America's Rent-Controlled Cities Are Its Least Affordable". Forbes. Archived from the original on 2015-07-19. Retrieved 2018-09-11.
- Valdez, Roger (2017-12-18). "Rent Control Doesn't Help Renters: Some In Washington State Want To Try It Anyway". Forbes. Archived from the original on 2017-12-23. Retrieved 2018-09-13.
- Rich, Spencer (1988-06-12). "Urban Institute, Leading Liberal Think Tank, Marks 20th Birthday". Los Angeles Times. Archived from the original on 2010-07-01. Retrieved 2018-08-20.
- Cohen, Rick (2014-12-12). "The Inner Workings of Think Tanks: Transparify Gives Us a Good Look". Nonprofit Quarterly. Archived from the original on 2016-05-31. Retrieved 2018-08-20.
... the Urban Institute, and others are typically considered nonpartisan or middle of the road.
- McLean, Jim (2014-11-20). "Kansas hospitals continue campaign for Medicaid expansion". Kansas Health Institute. Archived from the original on 2014-12-16. Retrieved 2018-08-20.
... the nonpartisan Urban Institute, ... .
- Pender, Kathleen (10 September 2016). "Rent control spreading to Bay Area suburbs, to economists' dismay". The San Francisco Chronicle. Archived from the original on 2016-10-08. Retrieved 2018-08-18.
- Jaffe, Eric (2013-04-09). "Some People Will Do Crazy Things for a Rent-Controlled Apartment in NYC". Bloomberg. CityLab - The Atlantic. Archived from the original on 2018-09-12. Retrieved 2018-09-11.
- "Nobelpristagaren i ekonomi 2008: Paul Krugman" Archived 2013-09-10 at the Wayback Machine, speech by Paul Krugman (Retrieved December 26, 2008)
- Sawhill, Ray (1999-11-10). "Black and right - Thomas Sowell talks about the arrogance of liberal elites and the loneliness of the black conservative". Salon. Archived from the original on 2011-12-07. Retrieved 2018-09-22.
- Sowell, Thomas. 2008. Economic Facts and Fallacies. Basic Books, ISBN 0-465-00349-4.
- Friedman, Milton D. (21 February 2011). "Roofs or Ceilings? The Current Housing Problem - Milton D. Friedman". Archived from the original on 9 March 2021. Retrieved 27 September 2011.
- Levine, Ned; Grigsby, J. Eugene; Heskin, Allan D. (1990). "Who Benefits from Rent Control? Effects on Tenants in Santa Monica, California". Journal of the American Planning Association. 56 (2): 140–152. doi:10.1080/01944369008975755.
- Heskin, Allan D.; Levine, Ned; Garrett, Mark (2000). "The Effects of Vacancy Control: A Spatial Analysis of Four California Cities". Journal of the American Planning Association. 66 (2): 162–176. doi:10.1080/01944360008976096. S2CID 153160869.
- Levine, Ned (November 1, 1999). "The Effects of Local Growth Controls on Regional Housing Production and Population Redistribution in California". Urban Studies. 36 (12): 2047–2068. doi:10.1080/0042098992539. S2CID 153734844.
- Diamond, Rebecca; McQuade, Tim; Qian, Franklin (2017-10-11). "The Effects of Rent Control Expansion on Tenants, Landlords, and Inequality: Evidence from San Francisco" (PDF). National Bureau of Economic Research. Archived (PDF) from the original on 2018-08-03. Retrieved 2018-08-07.
- Murphy, Katy (2017-11-02). "Rent-control policy 'likely fueled the gentrification of San Francisco,' study finds - As California debates rent caps, economists offer a cautionary note". The San Jose Mercury News. Archived from the original on 2018-01-04. Retrieved 2018-08-07.
- Truong, Kevin (2017-11-09). "Rent control linked to gentrification in San Francisco, Stanford study says". American City Business Journals. Archived from the original on 2018-12-02. Retrieved 2018-12-01.
- Robertson, Michelle (2017-11-03). "Rent-control policies likely 'fueled' SF gentrification, Stanford economists say". San Francisco Chronicle. Archived from the original on 2017-12-03. Retrieved 2018-08-07.
- Delgadillo, Natalie (2018-02-14). "Does Rent Control Do More Harm Than Good? - A new study suggests that policies meant to keep rents down actually jack them up overall, reduce the rental stock and fuel gentrification". Governing. Archived from the original on 2018-02-22. Retrieved 2018-08-07.
- Misra, Tanvi (2018-01-29). "Rent Control: a Reckoning". CityLab. Archived from the original on 2018-02-01. Retrieved 2018-11-30.
- Andrews, Edmund (2018-02-02). "Rent Control's Winners and Losers - With rents going through the roof in hot cities, the hunt is on for a better way to protect tenants from being priced out of their homes". Stanford Graduate School of Business. Archived from the original on 2018-03-09. Retrieved 2018-12-11.
- Raess, Pascal; von Ungern-Sternberg, Thomas (2002). "A model of regulation in the rental housing market". Regional Science and Urban Economics. 32 (4): 475–500. doi:10.1016/S0166-0462(01)00093-X.
- Čapek, Stella M (1992). Community versus Commodity: Tenants and the American City. ISBN 9780791498439. Archived from the original on 2021-03-09. Retrieved 2021-02-26.
- "Background history". Lower Manhattan Loft Tenants. 2002-01-01. Archived from the original on 2012-06-29.
As early as the mid-1960s, artists began pioneering the economically-depressed manufacturing zone of lower Manhattan known as SoHo where they found affordable "raw" or "as is" spaces large enough to both live and work (ie: lofts). Delighted to receive rent for these often abandoned, derelict spaces, commercial property owners welcomed and encouraged the residential occupancy of their buildings. Using sweat equity, artists renovated their leased lofts converting them into habitable living/working studios, installing plumbing and electrical fixtures along with other improvements--generally at their own expense. The City, which was equally delighted by the stabilization of the property tax base, turned a blind eye to the fact that none of these buildings had a residential Certificate of Occupancy.
- Diamond, Rebecca (2018-10-18). "What does economic evidence tell us about the effects of rent control?". Brookings. Retrieved 2021-03-23.
- "Research Shows Benefit of Decades-Old Affordable Housing Approach. NewsRoom". 3 April 2019. Archived from the original on 2020-11-07. Retrieved 2021-02-25.
- Schmitt, Noemi; Westerhoff, Frank (7 January 2021). "Speculative housing markets and rent control: insights from nonlinear economic dynamics - N Schmitt, F Westerhoff". Journal of Economic Interaction and Coordination. doi:10.1007/s11403-020-00312-3. S2CID 234298168.
- Krugman, Paul (2000-06-07). "Opinion | Reckonings; A Rent Affair". The New York Times. ISSN 0362-4331. Archived from the original on 2017-03-24. Retrieved 2019-10-21.
- Editorial Board (5 March 2019). "Rent control would benefit some tenants but sap vitality from Chicago". chicagotribune.com. Archived from the original on 2019-10-21. Retrieved 2019-10-21.
- Editorial Board. "Opinion | The economists are right: Rent control is bad". Washington Post. Archived from the original on 2019-10-21. Retrieved 2019-10-21.
- Board, The Editorial (29 September 2019). "Opinion | Bernie's National Rent Control". Wall Street Journal. Archived from the original on 2019-10-21. Retrieved 2019-10-21.
- Bautista, Rafael (2018-05-02). "In California, rent control is needed to protect working families". The San Diego Union-Tribune. Archived from the original on 2018-05-03. Retrieved 2018-08-09.
References
- Baar, Kenneth K. (1983). "Guidelines for Drafting Rent Control Laws: Lessons of a Decade." Rutgers Law Review, Vol. 35 No. 4 (Summer 1983).
- Baar, Kenneth K. (1992). "The Right to Sell the "Im"mobile Manufactured Home in Its Rent Controlled Space in the "Im"mobile Home Park: Valid Regulation or Unconstitutional Taking?" The Urban Lawyer, Vol. 24 pp. 157–221.
- Block, Walter (2008). "Rent Control". In David R. Henderson (ed.). Concise Encyclopedia of Economics (2nd ed.). Library of Economics and Liberty. ISBN 978-0-86597-665-8. OCLC 237794267.
- Downs, Anthony (1996). A Reevaluation of Residential Rent Controls. Washington, D.C. : Urban Land Institute, ISBN 0-87420-801-7.
- Friedman, Milton, and George J. Stigler (1946). Roofs or Ceilings? The Current Housing Problem. Irvington-on-Hudson, N.Y.: Foundation for Economic Education.
- Gilderbloom, John I., editor (1981). Rent Control: A Source Book. Center for Policy Alternatives; 3rd edition, June 1, 1981. ISBN 0-938806-01-7.
- Keating, Dennis, editor (1998). Rent Control: Regulation and the Housing Market. Center for Urban Policy Research, ISBN 0-88285-159-4.
- McDonough, Cristina (2007). "Rent Control and Rent Stabilization as Forms of Regulatory and Physical Taking." Boston College Environmental Affairs Law Review, Vol. 34 pp. 361–85.
- Niebanck, Paul L., editor (1986). The Rent Control Debate. University of North Carolina Press, ISBN 0-8078-1670-1.
- Tucker, William (1991). Zoning, Rent Control and Affordable Housing. ISBN 0-932790-78-X.
- Turner, Margery Austin (1990). Housing Market Impacts of Rent Control. Washington, D.C.: Urban Institute Press, ISBN 0-87766-443-9.
- Gilderbloom, John I.; Markham, John P. (1996). "Moderate Rent Control: Sixty Cities over 20 Years". Journal of Urban Affairs. 18 (4): 409–430. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9906.1996.tb00388.x.
External links
- Rent Control Around the World: Pros and Cons
- California cities with rent control
- additional California cities with rent regulation
- New York communities with rent control
- Pro-rent control article from tenant.net
- New York Magazine article on Rent Control including interviews with tenants
- Rent Control in the New Millennium by Dennis Keating
- Almanac of Policy Issues – Rent Controls
- Rent Controls and Housing Investment
- Pro-rent control article from Dollars & Sense magazine
- Four Thousand Years of Price Control – Mises Institute