Decommodification

In political economy, decommodification is the strength of social entitlements and citizens' degree of immunization from market dependency.[1][2]

In regards to the labor force, decommodification describes a "degree to which individual, or families, can uphold a socially acceptable standard of living independently of market participation."[3][4]

While commodification is the transformation of goods, services, ideas and people into commodities or objects of trade, decommodification would be the "extent that workers can leave the labor market through choice."[5]

Contemporary research

Gender inequality

The idea of decommodification as an egalitarian concept as set forth by Esping Andersen sparked contemporary research efforts focusing on perceived inequities. In 2008, a research journal pointed out a feminist critique that "the absolute focus on the welfare of individuals who are already working" leaves a central bias in the pursuit of decommodification.[6] Rather, the objective of women is often to be commodified in the first place so that they can enter the labor market.[7]

Environmental impact

Decommodification has been identified by ecological economists as a strategy for sustainable consumption that acts one level up on the institutional context of consumption in Western societies as compared to strategies such as eco-efficiency and eco-sufficiency.[8] Thus, while the eco-efficiency strategy targets the product and the eco-sufficiency strategy targets the person (the consumer as decision-maker), the decommodification strategy targets the institutional context in which consumption takes place. It aims to decrease the influence of commodities and to limit the effect of commercialization.

Social democracy paradox

Esping-Andersen's fundamental study of decommodification sparked contemporary academic research efforts hoping to resolve "paradoxes" in this application.[9][6] Exiting the labor market with little or no loss of income clashed with the idea that social democracy has the goal of high labor force participation. Research efforts to resolve this paradox showed that "employment impeding policies" came out of Christian democracy institutions, not social democracy institutions. This research suggests that decommodification in the social democratic model is viable.[6]

Example

Scandinavian countries are the closest to decommodification according to the scale created by Esping Andersen's research which places Sweden as the most decommodified country in the 1980s.[9] Sweden's level of pensions, sickness entitlements and unemployment insurance are the highest among many other leading industrial countries.[10] Sweden's social welfare programs are mandated by the government which also offers a de facto guarantee to the wages of citizens' rather than taking averages and creating regulations through a means-based test on citizens' wages, level of education and their past history with the law.[11]

Criticism

Several free market proponents, such as Austrian School philosophers Ludwig Mises and Murray Rothbard argue that markets are the best way to supply all goods or services efficiently. They say that providing services via the market reduces the effect of Government inefficiency.

Notes

  1. Janoski, Alford (2003). The Handbook of Political Sociology: States, Civil Societies, and Globalization (1st ed.). Cambridge. p. 511.
  2. Gerber, Jean-David; Gerber, Julien-François (2017). "Decommodification as a foundation for ecological economics". Ecological Economics. 131: 551–556. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2016.08.030.
  3. Esping-Andersen, Gøsta (1991). "The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism". Social Forces. 70 (2).
  4. Jacques, Olivier; Noël, Alain (2022). "Welfare state decommodification and population health". PLOS ONE. 17 (8): e0272698. doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0272698. PMC 9432727.
  5. Saunders, Peter (2017). Welfare to Work in Practice: Social Security and Participation in Economic and Social Life. Taylor and Francis. p. 107.
  6. Ho, JingJing (2008). "Decommodification and activation in social democratic policy: resolving the paradox". Journal of European Social Policy. 18 (1): 5–20. doi:10.1177/0958928707084449.
  7. Orloff, A.S (2004). "Gender and the Social Rights of Citizenship: the Comparative Analysis of Gender Relations and the Welfare State". American Sociological Review. 58 (3): 303. doi:10.2307/2095903.
  8. Boulanger, P.M. (2010) "Three strategies for sustainable consumption". S.A.P.I.EN.S. 3 (2)
  9. Anderson, Esping (1990). Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism. Princeton, N.J: Princeton University Press. ISBN 0691094578.
  10. Regeringskansliet, Regeringen och (2014-09-23). "Sveriges regering". Regeringskansliet (in Swedish). Retrieved 2018-12-10.
  11. "Minimum Income Schemes". ec.europa.eu. Retrieved 2018-12-10.
This article is issued from Wikipedia. The text is licensed under Creative Commons - Attribution - Sharealike. Additional terms may apply for the media files.