Rent-seeking

Rent-seeking is the act of growing one’s existing wealth without creating new wealth by manipulating the social or political environment.[1] Rent-seeking activities have negative effects on the rest of society. They result in reduced economic efficiency through misallocation of resources, reduced wealth creation, lost government revenue, heightened income inequality,[2] and potential national decline.

Attempts at capture of regulatory agencies to gain a coercive monopoly can result in advantages for rent-seekers in a market while imposing disadvantages on their uncorrupt competitors. This is one of many possible forms of rent-seeking behavior.

Description

The term rent-seeking was coined by the British 19th-century economist David Ricardo[3] but only became the subject of durable interest among economists and political scientists more than a century later after the publication of two influential papers on the topic by Gordon Tullock in 1967,[4] and Anne Krueger[5] in 1974. The word "rent" does not refer specifically to payment on a lease but rather to Adam Smith's division of incomes into profit, wage, and rent. The origin of the term refers to gaining control of land or other natural resources.

Georgist economic theory describes rent-seeking in terms of land rent, where the value of land largely comes from the natural resources native to the land, as well as collectively paid for services, for example: State schools, law enforcement, fire prevention and mitigation services etc. Rent seeking to the Georgist does not include those persons that may have invested substantial capital improvements to a piece of land, but rather those that perform in their role as mere titleholder. This is the dividing line between a rent-seeker and a property developer, which need not be the same person.

Rent-seeking is an attempt to obtain economic rent (i.e., the portion of income paid to a factor of production in excess of what is needed to keep it employed in its current use) by manipulating the social or political environment in which economic activities occur, rather than by creating new wealth. Rent-seeking implies extraction of uncompensated value from others without making any contribution to productivity. Because the nature of rent-seeking implies a fixed cost payment, only wealthy participants engage in these activities as a means of protecting their wealth from expropriation.[6]

In many market-driven economies, much of the competition for rents is legal, regardless of any harm it may do to an economy. However, various rent-seeking behaviors are illegal, such as the forming of cartels or the bribing of politicians.

Rent-seeking is distinguished in theory from profit-seeking, in which entities seek to extract value by engaging in mutually beneficial transactions.[7] Profit-seeking in this sense is the creation of wealth, while rent-seeking is "profiteering" by using social institutions, such as the power of the state, to redistribute wealth among different groups without creating new wealth.[8] In a practical context, income obtained through rent-seeking may contribute to profits in the standard, accounting sense of the word.

Tullock paradox

The Tullock paradox is the apparent paradox, described by economist Gordon Tullock, on the low costs of rent-seeking relative to the gains from rent-seeking.[9][10]

The paradox is that rent-seekers wanting political favors can bribe politicians at a cost much lower than the value of the favor to the rent-seeker. For instance, a rent seeker who hopes to gain a billion dollars from a particular political policy may need to bribe politicians with merely ten million dollars, which is about 1% of the gain to the rent-seeker. Luigi Zingales frames it by asking, "Why is there so little money in politics?" because a naïve model of political bribery and/or campaign spending should result in beneficiaries of government subsidies being willing to spend an amount up to the value of the subsidies themselves, when in fact only a small fraction of that is spent.[11]

Possible explanations

Several possible explanations have been offered for the Tullock paradox:[12]

  1. Voters may punish politicians who take large bribes, or live lavish lifestyles. This makes it hard for politicians to demand large bribes from rent-seekers.
  2. Competition between different politicians eager to offer favors to rent-seekers may bid down the cost of rent-seeking.
  3. Lack of trust between the rent-seekers and the politicians, due to the inherently underhanded nature of the deal and the unavailability of both legal recourse and reputational incentives to enforce compliance, pushes down the price that politicians can demand for favors.
  4. Rent-seekers can use a small part of the benefit gained to make contributions to the politicians who provided enabling legislation.

Examples

Antichristus,[13] a woodcut by Lucas Cranach the Elder, of the pope using the temporal power to grant authority to a ruler contributing generously to the Catholic Church

The classic example of rent-seeking, according to Robert Shiller, is that of a property owner who installs a chain across a river that flows through his land and then hires a collector to charge passing boats a fee to lower the chain. There is nothing productive about the chain or the collector. The owner has made no improvements to the river and is not adding value in any way, directly or indirectly, except for himself. All he is doing is finding a way to make money from something that used to be free.[14]

An example of rent-seeking in a modern economy is spending money on lobbying for government subsidies in order to be given wealth that has already been created, or to impose regulations on competitors, in order to increase market share.[15] Another example of rent-seeking is the limiting of access to lucrative occupations, as by medieval guilds or modern state certifications and licensures. According to some libertarian perspectives, taxi licensing is a textbook example of rent-seeking.[16] To the extent that the issuing of licenses constrains overall supply of taxi services (rather than ensuring competence or quality), forbidding competition from other vehicles for hire renders the (otherwise consensual) transaction of taxi service a forced transfer of part of the fee, from customers to taxi business proprietors.

The concept of rent-seeking would also apply to corruption of bureaucrats who solicit and extract "bribe" or "rent" for applying their legal but discretionary authority for awarding legitimate or illegitimate benefits to clients.[17] For example, tax officials may take bribes for lessening the tax burden of the taxpayers.

Regulatory capture is a related term for the collusion between firms and the government agencies assigned to regulate them, which is seen as enabling extensive rent-seeking behavior, especially when the government agency must rely on the firms for knowledge about the market. Studies of rent-seeking focus on efforts to capture special monopoly privileges such as manipulating government regulation of free enterprise competition.[18] The term monopoly privilege rent-seeking is an often-used label for this particular type of rent-seeking. Often-cited examples include a lobby that seeks economic regulations such as tariff protection, quotas, subsidies,[19] or extension of copyright law.[20] Anne Krueger concludes that "empirical evidence suggests that the value of rents associated with import licenses can be relatively large, and it has been shown that the welfare cost of quantitative restrictions equals that of their tariff equivalents plus the value of the rents".[5]

Rent-seeking through government enterprise takes the form of seeking subsidies and avoiding tariffs. This seems like the actions of a firm looking for investment in productivity but in doing so creates an exclusionary effect for more productive firms.[21]

Lotta Moberg presents an argument that export processing zones (EPZ) allow governments to choose exporting industries which receive tariffs allowing for rent seeking to take place. An example of this occurred in Latin America back in the 1960’s with Joaquín Balaguer’s response to pressure from the United States to open its export market. At the time, the United States was a massive trading partner for sugar while providing foreign aid, and military support which allowed his regime to take place. Joaquín Balaguer used EPZ to allow for some markets to remain tariffed while appeasing the markets facing political pressures. This created a sub-optimal environment for exporters as they were able to invest in rent seeking activities (lobbying) to gain access to EPZ to gain tax and tariff exemptions.[22]

In some cases, rent-seeking can provide a net positive for an economy. Shannon K. Mitchell’s article ‘The Welfare Effects of Rent-Saving and Rent-Seeking’ provides such an example through their model of rent seeking when firms need to expand to obtain their exporting rents.[23]

Economists such as Lord Adair Turner, the former chair of British financial regulator the Financial Services Authority, have argued that innovation in the financial industry is often a form of rent-seeking.[24][25]

Development of theory

The phenomenon of rent-seeking in connection with monopolies was first formally identified in 1967 by Gordon Tullock.[26]

A 2013 study by the World Bank showed that the incentives for policy-makers to engage in rent-provision is conditional on the institutional incentives they face, with elected officials in stable high-income democracies the least likely to indulge in such activities vis-à-vis entrenched bureaucrats and/or their counterparts in young and quasi-democracies.[27]

Criticism

In the 1980s, the critiques of rent-seeking theory began to emerge by questioning the ambiguity of 'wasted resources' and the reliability of the assumptions being made on them.[28] Samuels argues that productivity is being defined as a strictly physical property and ignores the rights that surround and define the product. The second argument he brings is rent-seeking theorist ignore a fundamental principle of being economic actors, that we live in markets of scarce resources and it’s how we utilise these resources drives supply and demand, and ‘wasted resources’ rejects our preferences to allocate those resources.[28]

Writing in The Review of Austrian Economics, Ernest C. Pasour says that there may be difficulties distinguishing between beneficial profit-seeking and detrimental rent-seeking.[29]

Possible consequences

From a theoretical standpoint, the moral hazard of rent-seeking can be considerable. If "buying" a favorable regulatory environment seems cheaper than building more efficient production, a firm may choose the former option, reaping incomes entirely unrelated to any contribution to total wealth or well-being. This results in a sub-optimal allocation of resources – money spent on lobbyists and counter-lobbyists rather than on research and development, on improved business practices, on employee training, or on additional capital goods – which slows economic growth. Claims that a firm is rent-seeking therefore often accompany allegations of government corruption, or the undue influence of special interests.[30]

Rent-seeking can prove costly to economic growth; high rent-seeking activity makes more rent-seeking attractive because of the natural and growing returns that one sees as a result of rent-seeking. Thus organizations value rent-seeking over productivity. In this case there are very high levels of rent-seeking with very low levels of output. Rent-seeking may grow at the cost of economic growth because rent-seeking by the state can easily hurt innovation. Ultimately, public rent-seeking hurts the economy the most because innovation drives economic growth.[31]

Government agents may initiate rent-seeking – such agents soliciting bribes or other favors from the individuals or firms that stand to gain from having special economic privileges, which opens up the possibility of exploitation of the consumer.[32] It has been shown that rent-seeking by bureaucracy can push up the cost of production of public goods.[33] It has also been shown that rent-seeking by tax officials may cause loss in revenue to the public exchequer.[17]

Mançur Olson traced the historic consequences of rent seeking in The Rise and Decline of Nations. As a country becomes increasingly dominated by organized interest groups, it loses economic vitality and falls into decline. Olson argued that countries that have a collapse of the political regime and the interest groups that have coalesced around it can radically improve productivity and increase national income because they start with a clean slate in the aftermath of the collapse. An example of this is Japan after World War Two. But new coalitions form over time, once again shackling society in order to redistribute wealth and income to themselves. However, social and technological changes have allowed new enterprises and groups to emerge.[34]

A study by Laband and John Sophocleus in 1988[35] estimated that rent-seeking had decreased total income in the US by 45 percent. Both Dougan and Tullock affirm the difficulty of finding the cost of rent-seeking. Rent-seekers of government-provided benefits will in turn spend up to that amount of benefit in order to gain those benefits, in the absence of, for example, the collective-action constraints highlighted by Olson. Similarly, taxpayers lobby for loopholes and will spend the value of those loopholes, again, to obtain those loopholes (again absent collective-action constraints). The total of wastes from rent-seeking is then the total amount from the government-provided benefits and instances of tax avoidance (valuing benefits and avoided taxes at zero). Dougan says that the "total rent-seeking costs equal the sum of aggregate current income plus the net deficit of the public sector".[36]

Mark Gradstein writes about rent-seeking in relation to public goods provision, and says that public goods are determined by rent seeking or lobbying activities. But the question is whether private provision with free-riding incentives or public provision with rent-seeking incentives is more inefficient in its allocation.[37]

Political rent-seeking can also affect immigration. Welfare states incentivise unproductive migration and can create continuation of past behaviour of not accumulating personal wealth and being dependent on government transfers.[38] Alternatively, productive migrants are incentivised to leave rent-seeking societies, possibly resulting in further economic decline.[39] Low-income countries are often rent-seeking societies, that productive people will likely seek to leave.[40]

The Nobel Memorial Prize-winning economist Joseph Stiglitz has argued that rent-seeking contributes significantly to income inequality in the United States through lobbying for government policies that let the wealthy and powerful get income, not as a reward for creating wealth, but by grabbing a larger share of the wealth that would otherwise have been produced without their effort.[41][42] Thomas Piketty, Emmanuel Saez, and Stefanie Stantcheva have analyzed international economies and their changes in tax rates to conclude that much of income inequality is a result of rent-seeking among wealthy tax payers.[43]

Laband and John Sophocleus suggest that the lack of empirical evidence on rent-seeking is due to the broad scope of rent-seeking and rent avoidance activities. Additionally, they suggest that many economic performance measures, such as Gross Domestic Product, include goods and services that are part of the rent-seeking process.[44]

See also

References

  1. Compare: "rent-seeking". Oxford English Dictionary (Online ed.). Oxford University Press. (Subscription or participating institution membership required.) - "rent-seeking n. Economics[:] the fact or process of seeking to gain larger profits by manipulating public policy or economic conditions, esp. by means of securing beneficial subsidies or tariffs, making a product artificially scarce, etc. [...]"
  2. IMF. "Rent-seeking and Endogenous Income Inequality" (PDF). Retrieved 30 April 2014.
  3. Henderson, David R. "Rent Seeking". Econlib.org.
  4. Tullock, Gordon (1967). "The Welfare Costs of Tariffs, Monopolies and Theft". Western Economic Journal. 5: 224–232.
  5. Krueger, Anne (1974). "The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society". American Economic Review. 64 (3): 291–303. JSTOR 1808883.
  6. Chakraborty, Shankha (2005). Rent Seeking. IMF Working Papers. Vol. 05. International Monetary Fund. p. 1. doi:10.5089/9781451860627.001. ISBN 9781451860627. ISSN 1018-5941. S2CID 15557383.
  7. Schenk, Robert. "Rent Seeking". CyberEconomics. Archived from the original on 3 January 2006. Retrieved 11 February 2007.
  8. Conybeare, John A. C. (1982). "The Rent-Seeking State and Revenue Diversification". World Politics. 35 (1): 25–42. doi:10.2307/2010278. JSTOR 2010278. S2CID 154601921.
  9. Tullock, Gordon (1980). "Efficient rent-seeking". In Buchanan, J.; Tollison, R.; Tullock, G. (eds.). Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society. College Station: Texas A&M Press. pp. 97–112. ISBN 0-89096-090-9.
  10. Connes, Richard; Hartley, Roger (September 2003). "Loss Aversion and the Tullock Paradox". University of Nottingham Economics Discussion Paper (3/17). CiteSeerX 10.1.1.624.4082. SSRN 467901. RePEc:kee:kerpuk:2003/06.
  11. Zingales, Luigi (5 June 2012). A Capitalism for the People: Recapturing the Lost Genius of American Prosperity. Basic Books. ISBN 978-0-465-02947-1 via Google Books.
  12. Zingales, Luigi (2014). A Capitalism for the People: Recapturing the Lost Genius of American Prosperity. Basic Books. pp. 75–78. ISBN 9780465038701.
  13. Luther, Martin (1521). Passional Christi und Antichristi.
  14. Shiller, Robert (20 September 2013). "The Best, Brightest and Least Productive?". project-syndicate.org. Project Syndicate.
  15. Samples, John (30 May 2012). "An Introduction to Rent Seeking". libertarianism.org.
  16. McTaggart, Douglas (2012). Economics. Pearson Higher Education. p. 224. ISBN 978-1-4425-5077-3.
  17. Chowdhury, Faizul Latif (2006). Corrupt Bureaucracy and Privatization of Tax Enforcement in Bangladesh. Pathak Shamabesh, Dhaka. ISBN 978-984-8120-62-0.
  18. Feenstra, Robert; Taylor, Alan (2008). International Economics. New York: Worth Publishers. ISBN 978-0-7167-9283-3.
  19. Rowley, Charles Kershaw (1988). The Political Economy of Rent-Seeking. Springer. p. 226. ISBN 978-0-89838-241-9.
  20. Saperstein, Lanier (1997). "Copyrights, Criminal Sanctions and Economic Rents: Applying the Rent Seeking Model to the Criminal Law Formulation Process". The Journal of Criminal Law and Criminology. 87 (4): 1470–1510. doi:10.2307/1144023. JSTOR 1144023.
  21. Baohua, Liu; Yan, Lin; Kam.C, Chan; Hung-Gay, Fung (2018). "The dark side of rent-seeking: The impact of rent-seeking on earnings management". Journal of Business Research. 91 (1): 94–107. doi:10.1016/j.jbusres.2018.05.037. S2CID 158315455.
  22. Moberg, Lotta (2018). "Liberalizing rent-seeking: How export processing zones can save or sink an economy". Journal of Private Enterprise. Texas: Association of Private Enterprise Education. 33 (4): 61–89. ISSN 0890-913X.
  23. Shannon, Mitchell (1993). "The Welfare Effects of Rent-Saving and Rent-Seeking". The Canadian Journal of Economics. Wiley on behalf of the Canadian Economics Association. 26 (3): 660–669. doi:10.2307/135893. JSTOR 135893.
  24. Turner, Adair (19 April 2012). Securitisation, Shadow Banking and the Value of Financial Innovation (PDF) (Report). School of Advanced International Studies. Johns Hopkins University. Archived from the original (PDF) on 3 October 2012.
  25. Turner, Adair (17 March 2010). What do banks do, what should they do and what public policies are needed to ensure best results for the real economy? (PDF) (Speech). FSA.gov.uk. Archived from the original (PDF) on 7 October 2010.[?]
  26. Tullock, Gordon (1967). "The Welfare Costs of Tariffs, Monopolies, and Theft". Western Economic Journal. 5 (3): 224–32. doi:10.1111/j.1465-7295.1967.tb01923.x.
  27. Hamilton, Alexander (2013). "Small Is Beautiful, at Least in High-Income Democracies : The Distribution of Policy-Making Responsibility, Electoral Accountability, and Incentives for Rent Extraction". Policy Research Working Paper; No. 6305. Washington, DC: World Bank. hdl:10986/12197.
  28. Samuels, W. J. (1992). "A Critique of Rent-seeking Theory". Essays on the Economic Role of Government. 2: 111–128. doi:10.1007/978-1-349-12377-3_6. ISBN 978-1-349-12379-7.
  29. Pasour, E. C. (1987). "Rent Seeking: Some Conceptual Problems and Implications" (PDF). The Review of Austrian Economics. 1 (1): 123–143. doi:10.1007/BF01539337. S2CID 18809359.
  30. Eisenhans, Hartmut (1996). State, class, and development. Radiant Publishers. ISBN 978-81-7027-214-4.
  31. Murphy, Kevin; Shleifer, Andrei; Vishny, Robert (1993). "Why is Rent-Seeking So Costly to Growth?". American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings. 83 (2): 409–414. JSTOR 2117699.
  32. Michael Dauderstädt; Arne Schildberg, eds. (2006). Dead Ends of Transition: Rentier Economies and Protectorates. Campus Verlag. ISBN 978-3-593-38154-1.
  33. Niskanen, William (1971). Bureaucracy and Representative Government. Aldine-Atherton, Chicago. ISBN 9780202060408.
  34. Mokyr, Joel; Nye, John V. C. (2007). "Distributional Coalitions, the Industrial Revolution, and the Origins of Economic Growth in Britain" (PDF). Southern Economic Journal. 74 (1): 50–70. doi:10.1002/j.2325-8012.2007.tb00826.x. RePEc:sej:ancoec:v:74:1:y:2007:p:50-70. Archived from the original (PDF) on 16 December 2019.
  35. Leeson, Peter T. (2009). The Invisible Hook: The Hidden Economics of Pirates. Princeton University Press. p. 191. ISBN 9780691150093. JSTOR j.ctt7t3fh.
  36. Dougan, William R. (1991). "The Cost of Rent Seeking: Is GNP Negative?". Journal of Political Economy. 99 (3): 660–664. doi:10.1086/261773. S2CID 154489617.
  37. Gradstein, Mark (1993). "Rent Seeking and the Provision of Public Goods". The Economic Journal. 103 (420): 1236–1243. doi:10.2307/2234249. JSTOR 2234249.
  38. Nannestad, Peter. "Taxing the rich or the poor?: Immigrants on the dole as the socially optimal policy outcome for rational egalitarians". researchgate. Res. Retrieved 3 May 2022.
  39. Hillman, Ayre. "Rent Seeking". researchgate. Retrieved 3 May 2022.
  40. Hillman, Ayre. "Rent Seeking". researchgate. {{cite web}}: Missing or empty |url= (help)
  41. Stiglitz, Joseph E. (4 June 2012). The Price of Inequality: How Today's Divided Society Endangers Our Future. p. 32. Norton. Kindle Edition.
  42. Lind, Michael (22 March 2013). "How rich "moochers" hurt America". Salon. Retrieved 7 April 2013.
  43. Piketty, Thomas; Saez, Emmanuel; Stantcheva, Stefanie (2014). "Optimal Taxation of Top Labor Incomes: A Tale of Three Elasticities" (PDF). American Economic Journal: Economic Policy. 6 (1): 230–71. doi:10.1257/pol.6.1.230. S2CID 13028796.
  44. Laband, David; Sophocleus, John. "Measuring rent-seeking". researchgate. Retrieved 3 May 2022.

Further reading

  • Chowdhury, Faizul Latif (2006). Corrupt Bureaucracy and Privatization of Tax Enforcement in Bangladesh. Dhaka: Pathak Shamabesh. pp. 25–34. ISBN 978-984-8120-62-0.
  • Ikeda, Sanford (2008). "Rent Seeking". In Hamowy, Ronald (ed.). The Encyclopedia of Libertarianism. Thousand Oaks, CA: SAGE; Cato Institute. pp. 422–23. doi:10.4135/9781412965811.n259. ISBN 978-1412965804. LCCN 2008009151. OCLC 750831024.
  • Tullock, Gordon (1987). "Rent seeking". The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics. Vol. 4. Palgrave Macmillan. 147–49. ISBN 978-0-333-37235-7.
  • Tullock, Gordon (2005). The Rent-Seeking Society: The Selected Works of Gordon Tullock, Vol. 5.
This article is issued from Wikipedia. The text is licensed under Creative Commons - Attribution - Sharealike. Additional terms may apply for the media files.